49226

LEVERAGED BUYOUTS

Their impact on jobs and wages

Kevin Amess

Sometimes private equity … give the impression of being little more than amoral asset-strippers after a quick buck. Casino capitalists enjoying huge personal windfalls from deals at the same time as they gamble with other people’s futures. (Brendan Barber. General Secretary of Trade Union Congress, 2007)

Introduction

Leveraged buyouts (LBOs) are corporate restructuring transactions involving the transfer of whole companies or company divisions to new owners. There are two key features typical of all LBO transactions: first, a high level of debt, secured against an LBO target’s corporate assets and future cash flows, is used to facilitate an LBO transaction; second, senior management possesses a significant equity stake after the buyout (Thompson & Wright, 1995; Kaplan & Stromberg, 2009). There are, however, variations in types of LBO transactions. For instance, insider-driven deals, where incumbent managers in a firm acquire a significant equity stake, are referred to as management buyouts; while outsider-driven deals, where outside managers acquire a significant equity stake are referred to as management buyins (MBIs) (Thompson & Wright, 1995).

LBOs install a system of corporate governance that provides managers with strong incentives to focus on profitability (Jensen, 1986; Thompson & Wright, 1995). First, a significant proportion of equity is held by management.1 This unifies senior management with ownership, providing managers with a strong incentive to focus on firm profitability. Second, the fixed interest obligation of debt requires managers to pay out future cash flows rather than waste cash on sub-optimal investments and perquisites. Third, in the case of private equity (PE)-backed deals, PE firms will hold a significant equity stake and have board representation. The high equity stake provides financial incentives for PE firms to monitor senior management and provide input into strategic decisions. PE firms’ board representation facilitates their monitoring function and input into strategic decisions. Consistent with the view that LBOs install strong corporate governance is evidence that LBOs are associated with real economic performance gains (Lichtenberg & Siegel, 1990; Amess, 2003; Harris et al., 2005; Davis et al., 2014).

493While there is little academic debate that LBOs are associated with performance gains, there has been a great deal of controversy in academia and in wider society concerning their impact on jobs and wages. In some respects PE might seem a distant “world of high finance” to workers, but where PE can directly impact on workers is through jobs and wages. This real effect brings the PE business model directly into workers’ lives. It should not be surprising, therefore, that the debate concerning LBOs’ real impact on jobs and wages has sometimes been visceral. The concern is not simply that workers lose jobs and suffer lower wages as a result of a PE-backed LBO, it is that PE investors’ wealth gains might partly be achieved by such restricting decisions (Fox & Marcus, 1992; International Trade Union Confederation, 2007; Applebaum & Batt, 2014). In sum, the LBO restructuring transaction creates an opportunity for the revision of labor contracts and investors exploit this for personal gain. The competing argument from practitioners and proponents of LBOs is that they target firms that are underperforming and that the restructuring of portfolio firms is required in order to create sustainable businesses. PE firms realize capital gains when they sell their portfolio firms on at a profit and this can only be achieved if they create viable businesses.

This review focuses on providing a synthesis of the evidence obtained from quantitative empirical studies concerning the impact of LBOs (with insider or outsider management involvement) on jobs and wages. The focus is on these studies because they provide objective evidence of the average effect within large samples. This has the benefit of being able to provide insights that shed light on competing arguments concerning the labor effects of LBOs, whereas a use of case studies might illicit an accusation that a specific case was chosen to support a specific argument. In addition, given intermittent calls for government intervention on PE firms’ activity to protect workers’ welfare, a synthesis of large-scale studies provides the best basis for understanding the overall effects of LBOs on jobs and wages.

Theoretical perspectives

Agency theory

The seminal work of Jensen (1986) provides an agency theory perspective through which LBOs have traditionally been understood. The corporate governance literature recognizes that when ownership and management of a firm are separated, management might have the discretion to pursue different objectives from firms’ owners, creating agency costs. These agency costs are most severe in the presence of weak corporate governance that does not attenuate managers’ discretionary behavior. Discretionary behavior could include the pursuit of firm size beyond its optimal level and making investments that yield a negative net present value. This could result in job creation from which management obtain private benefit. Such discretionary behavior reduces firm value and performance (Jensen & Meckling, 1976; Fama & Jensen, 1983; Hart, 1995). An LBO installs a governance structure that realigns managers’ objectives with those of the owners, reducing discretionary behavior (Jensen, 1986, Thompson & Wright, 1995).

The agency theory perspective of LBOs is associated with job losses because restructuring after a LBO sometimes involves downsizing and downscoping a firm in order to improve its performance. If pre-LBO management pursued discretionary goals that required more employees beyond the optimal level, an LBO provides an opportunity and incentives for a correction in employment levels. The agency theory perspective therefore predicts a reduction in employment levels after an LBO. Job losses in these circumstances have become associated with the PE business model. Critics argue that PE firms create wealth 494for investors by cutting jobs and that the wealth created for investors is in part created from transfers from employees. The agency theory perspective makes it clear that such jobs were the result of managerial discretion that reduced firm value and performance. This is therefore a sub-optimal use of employees. Moreover, practitioners argue that their goal is not to destroy jobs per se, but to create sustainable businesses.

The change in ownership at the time of an LBO provides an opportunity for wage payments that exceed the marginal product of labor to be reduced (Shleifer & Summers, 1988). The implication here is that the LBO is not creating wealth; rather, it is motivated by the transfer of wealth from employees to LBO investors. Such rent-extraction could pay off for LBO investors in the short term if employees who have made investments in firm-specific human capital do not leave their jobs because the next-best paid job pays no better than the post-LBO lower wage. In the long term, however, the lower wages reduce incentives to invest in firm-specific human capital, lowering labor productivity (Shleifer & Summers, 1988). There could also be a short-term negative impact on labor productivity if effort is reduced because the higher wage payments are perceived by employees as a norm and part of an implicit agreement in return for a “fair day’s work” (Akerlof, 1982).

Contrary to the above is an argument that organizational restructuring results in employees receiving higher wages after an LBO. Lichtenberg and Siegel (1990) suggest that wages could replace monitoring by bureaucratic staff after an LBO in order to reduce employee moral hazard. An efficiency wage argument is that wages are paid at a rate to maximize labor productivity, which is in excess of the equilibrium market clearing level (Stiglitz, 1987). Employee moral hazard is reduced because the higher wage payment increases the cost of losing a job by being caught shirking. Another explanation is that a higher wage establishes a norm where employees are willing to put in more effort in return for higher pay (Akerlof, 1982). This theoretical argument predicts an increase in wages after an LBO.

Entrepreneurial

The entrepreneurial perspective is a more recent addition to our understanding of the impact of the LBO governance structure and the role that PE firms play in their interaction with portfolio firms. The entrepreneurial perspective offers an understanding of the LBO of divisions/subsidiaries of larger organizations and the LBO of private firms. These arguments are important because both these types of LBOs represent a large proportion of deals that are conducted (Kaplan & Stromberg, 2009).

Arguments relating to the LBO of divisions/subsidiaries are outlined first. Williamson (1975, 1985) argues that large organizations adopt a divisional organizational structure with an internal capital market. It exists due to the failure of the external capital market. Head office allocates cash to divisions, which are profit centers, where it can get the best return on investment. Such an organizational structure acts as an incentive and governance device to promote profit maximization from divisional managers. There are, however, limits to the effectiveness of the internal capital market of large firms as an incentive and governance device (Williamson, 1985). The misallocation of resources can occur due to divisional managers politicking to gain access to financial resources, which could result in under-investment in some divisions. Under-investment in a division might also arise as a consequence of head office deciding that a division does not feature in its core strategy. Under-investment in divisions could result in sub-optimally low levels of employment.

In the case of private firms, they can suffer from under-investment due to their reliance on internal finance (Carpenter & Petersen, 2002) and difficulties in obtaining finance from 495banks (Behr et al., 2013). This is because private firms find it difficult to convey information about their creditworthiness to external finance providers (Behr et al., 2013). In addition, some private firms might pursue alternative goals to profit-maximization (e.g., lifestyle businesses and family-run businesses).

The entrepreneurial perspective emphasizes both entrepreneurial incentives and the relaxation of financial constraints leading to investment in profitable growth opportunities. First, the equity held by management provides financial incentives to pursue entrepreneurial growth opportunities. This contrasts with hierarchical incentives that can sometimes fail to motivate managers’ pursuit of entrepreneurial growth (Thompson & Wright, 1995). Where PE firms hold a significant equity stake, they promote and encourage value creation through their involvement in the entrepreneurial decision-making of their portfolio firms (Bruining et al., 2012). Second, PE firms also have the potential to relax pre-buyout financial constraints and increase investment in entrepreneurial activity (Berger & Udell, 1998; Engel & Stiebale, 2014). This is a result of their role in improving post-LBO governance and their financial expertise reassuring creditors that funds will be used productively (Boucly et al., 2011; Amess et al., 2015).

The entrepreneurial perspective’s emphasis on incentives to pursue profitable growth opportunities suggests that LBOs have the potential to create jobs. Note, however, that the entrepreneurial perspective offers no insight on LBOs’ effects on wages. Nevertheless, a positive effect on wages would suggest that employees share in potential gains from investment in growth opportunities. If there is no wage effect, it suggests that post-LBO investors do not share their entrepreneurial gains with employees.

The PE business model

While the theoretical perspectives above provide an academic framework for understanding the impact of LBOs on jobs and wages, the nature of the PE business model has also received attention for how it impacts on jobs and wages. Broadly there are two competing views. First, there is criticism that the PE business model involves job cuts and the suppression of wages in portfolio firms in order to generate profit for the new owners. Critics have focused on PE firms in particular because their business model involves targeting, buying, restructuring, and selling firms in order to make a capital gain for themselves and their investors. When restructuring has resulted in job losses, critics have not perceived it necessary to create a sustainable business; rather, it is perceived as a short-term measure to create profit for LBO investors at employees’ expense.

Second, proponents argue that PE firms acquire underperforming firms and develop them into sustainable businesses. The PE business model is able to create value by targeting underperforming firms and restructuring their financial incentives, governance, and business operations. With larger deals short-term organizational restructuring that involves downscoping might be required in order to correct prior mistakes that led to over-diversification. This will lead to job losses, but the purpose of downscoping is to create a more strategically focused and sustainable business. In smaller deals the value creation is through the purchase of neglected divisions and poorly run private firms. In these cases, value creation arises through the exploitation of business opportunities, creating jobs.

While there are some general features of an LBO deal, there are different motivations. There are variations in the business models applied in order to create value in portfolio firms. Many academic studies do not take this into consideration, however; rather, they assess an average effect or examine effects across different employees’ types while neglecting the different business models applied by PE firms in their attempt to create value.

496Employment effects

The empirical studies discussed in this section are listed in Table 26.1. Details of the sample, including: country of study, sample period, and number of firms subject to an LBO are provided in the table. Where establishment- and employee-level data have been used, the number of establishments and the number of employees subject to an LBO are also provided. The deal type and summary of key findings are also reported in Table 26.1. Given that these details can be found in Table 26.1, the focus of the discussion below will be on the findings reported.

Table 26.1      Summary of employment studies reviewed in chronological order

image

497image

498image

It can be seen from the sample descriptions in Table 26.1 that most studies use samples from the US and the UK, reflecting the preponderance of deals in these markets. While this review does include studies using Swedish, German, and French data, it is clear that there is scope for further examination of the employment consequences of LBOs in different countries with different institutional contexts.

Average effects

Some of the early research examining employment consequences reflects difficulties in obtaining data for private firms at that time. Therefore, the relatively small samples reflect a focus on PTP deals where pre-LBO data is easy to obtain. Kaplan (1986) reports a 12% decline in median industry-adjusted employment from the year prior to the MBO deal to the year afterwards; however, this result included a sample of firms that undertook divestitures and acquisitions. For a subsample of firms that did not undertake divestment or acquisition, Kaplan does not find any statistically significant association between MBOs and employment. Smith (1990) also finds an insignificant industry-adjusted employment effect. Thus, these early US studies found that there was no employment effect associated with PTP buyouts.

While the early US research outlined earlier focused on the employment effects in PTP transactions, early UK research by Wright et al. (1992) examined the average employment effects across a range of deal sources (e.g., family and divestment). They obtain data via a survey conducted in 1990 of deals between 1983 and 1986. The survey found that employment was 6.3% lower at the time of the MBO and remained 4.5% lower at the time of the survey. The results must be treated with caution, however, because no control sample was used.

Bergstrom et al. (2007) provide evidence from a sample of Swedish PE-backed buyouts. The deals have no significant impact on employment. This is supported by Amess and Wright (2012), who examine the average employment effects of deals from a variety of deal sources (i.e., public, private, divestment, receivership). A feature of the study is that it distinguishes between PE-backed and non-PE-backed deals. Using an employment demand equation, they 499find that LBOs, whether PE-backed or not, have no significant impact on employment levels. They also find that the impact on employment growth is also insignificant after accounting for large deals where there is expected to be more restructuring and likelihood of job losses.

A fundamental problem when analyzing the impact of LBOs is establishing the counterfactual. Firms subject to a LBO are not randomly selected from the population of firms, and it might be the case that employment levels impact on the LBO decision. For instance, over-employment might be identified as a source of underperformance in a firm, making it an LBO target with job reduction a potential source of performance gains. Amess et al.’s (2014) study of PE-backed and non-PE-backed LBOs use two modeling strategies to address the issue of self-selection to the LBO form. Average treatment effects are estimated using difference-in-differences (DiD) combined with propensity score matching (PSM) and the control function approach. The application of these methods reveals that estimates of employment effects can be sensitive to modelling strategy. First, estimates obtained from DiD combined with PSM indicate that, over the period t−1 to t+1 around the deal, PE-backed LBOs have no significant effect on employment while non-PE-backed LBOs experience an 11% decline in employment. Second, the control function approach indicates that, over the period t−1 to t+2 around the deal, PE-backed LBOs experience a 9% increase in employment while there is no significant effect on non-PE-backed LBOs. This evidence shows that, at best, PE-backed LBOs create jobs while non-PE-backed LBOs have no significant impact on jobs.

Davis et al. (2014) conduct one of the most comprehensive studies to date by analyzing the employment effects of PE-backed LBOs at both establishment and firm levels. The study excludes MBOs that do not involve a PE firm, which means they are unable to compare the consequences of PE-backed and non-PE-backed deals. Their analysis provides a number of insights. First, average employment levels shrink more rapidly at establishments subject to an LBO compared to controls. Davis et al. find that the cumulative difference in favour of controls is about 3% and 6% of initial employment over the first two and five years post-LBO, respectively. Second, in shrinking and exiting establishments LBOs experience faster job destruction than control firms, but in expanding establishments there is faster job creation than control firms. Third, over the two years after an LBO, target firms exhibit nearly 2% more greenfield job creation than controls. Summing over job creation and destruction at continuing establishment, job losses at closed establishments, job gains at greenfield establishments, acquisitions and divestitures, employment declines by less than 1% compared to controls t+2 after LBO. The results reveal that PE-backed LBOs are catalysts for a process of creative destruction that would be hidden from firm-level studies.

Connections between business and politics are contentious. There is concern that business exploits political connections to get favorable treatment (e.g., through more favorable labor laws), but collaboration between business and politics can help create an environment conducive to job creation. Faccio and Hsu (2017) explore the issue of political connections by examining the impact of PE firms’ political connections on employment. They find that over the period t−1 to t+5 employment grows, on average, by 1.24% in establishments controlled by politically connected PE firms while in nonconnected PE firms it is 0.33%. After addressing endogeneity concerns, there is still a significant difference in employment growth between the politically connected and nonconnected PE firms, but the magnitudes are more modest. Nevertheless, Faccio and Hsu (2017) argue their findings could be due to politicians and PE firms exchanging favors. They find evidence consistent with politically connected PE firms altering their hiring and firing decisions to support the election of their political allies. In return, portfolio firms of politically connected PE firms receive government grants and contracts. This provides an important understanding of decision-making in 500portfolio firms because it suggests that job creation and destruction after a PE-backed LBO is not a simply a business decision.

Differences across deal type and source

There is recognition in the literature that the impact of LBOs could vary across deal type and source of deal. Amess and Wright (2007) seek to draw a distinction between MBOs (insider-driven deals) and MBIs (outsider-driven deals). Managers with inside information might be in a better position to exploit untapped growth opportunities and might have loyalty to existing employees. In contrast, the outsiders in an MBI, with less loyalty to existing employees, might be more inclined to restructure, leading to job losses. They find that employment growth is 0.51 of a percentage point higher in MBOs and 0.81 of a percentage point lower in MBIs, compared to a control sample of firms. The authors suggest that for the average MBO in their sample employment grows by about 1.5 employees per year, while for the average MBI in their sample employment declines by about 5 employees per year. Economically, these figures are fairly modest. Nevertheless, they indicate that a distinction between MBOs and MBIs matters and not all LBOs will have the same employment effects. Moreover, MBOs seem to be able to obtain previously untapped employment growth opportunities while MBIs are associated with job losses, possibly due to restructuring.

Subsequent analysis of outsider-driven deals, i.e., institutional buy outs (IBOs), by Georgen et al. (2011, 2014) also find they are associated with negative employment effects. IBOs are deals where the acquirer consists solely of institutional investors and PE firms c.f. MBIs where outside managers are also part of the team of acquirers. Georgen et al. (2011) report that employment growth is 1.62% lower in the year after the deal but IBO employment growth is not statistically significant from a control sample of firms two and three years after the deal. Georgen et al. (2014) report that post-IBO employment is up to 15% lower.

Most studies do not distinguish between deal sources. Meuleman et al. (2009) and Boucly et al. (2011) examine the employment effect of different deal sources in order to explore deals where there are most likely to be entrepreneurial growth opportunities. Meuleman et al. (2009) find that employment growth is 36% higher in divisional buyouts compared with other deal sources over the three years after the deal. This heterogeneity in employment effects across deal sources is also reported in Boucly et al. (2011). While they find that average employment for all LBOs grows by 12% from the year before the deal to three years after the deal, employment grows by 18% in private-to-private deals, 11% in secondary buyouts (SBOs) and 6% in divisional buyouts. Employment growth in private-to-private and divisional buyout deals could be due to the entrepreneurial incentives installed by an LBO. The SBO result is curious because the governance and entrepreneurial incentives are in place prior to the SBO. Given that industry expertise can improve portfolio firms’ operations (Bernstein & Sheen, 2016), one possible explanation is that SBOs occur when there is better complementarity between portfolio firms’ assets and the acquiring PE firms’ expertise (e.g., specialist market knowledge) than that for the selling PE firm. As a consequence, the PE firm in the SBO might be able to achieve growth opportunities, resulting in employment growth, which are not achieved in the primary deal.

The impact on different types of workers

One branch of the literature recognizes that the impact of an LBO might result in organizational change that has a distinctive impact for different types of workers. Lichtenberg 501and Siegel (1990) examine the different employment consequences for nonproduction and production workers. They find that there is an 8.5% reduction in the number of nonproduction workers employed while there is no significant effect on production workers. This is consistent with an agency perspective where bureaucratic employees that are costly and do not create or add productive value are stripped out of plants. In contrast, production workers might not suffer job losses because their activities create value for firms.

The distinction between different worker types has been neglected in the literature for a number of years, reflecting the difficulty in obtaining such data because it is not reported in company reports; however, two recent studies use government employee-level data that allows in-depth analysis of employment consequences for employees with different characteristics. Antoni et al. (2015) find modest average effects on employment; the fraction of a year an employee is employed falls by about 1–1.5%. An important insight from their study, however, is that employment effects vary across employee characteristics. Employees that are older, those with a longer tenure in their jobs, female, white-collar and unskilled blue-collar workers experience increased risk of unemployment. Tåg and Olsson (2016) find little evidence of average changes in employment incidence after a PE-backed LBO. For specific worker types in low productivity firms, however, there are negative employment effects. Workers performing routine job tasks experience a 10.2 percentage point (96.6%) increase in employment incidence and workers performing offshorable job tasks experience an 8.6 percentage point (97%) increase in unemployment incidence. Such detailed analyses suggests that LBO restructuring impacts on workers differently. Such effects are not captured in studies examining average effects across a workforce.

Agrawal and Tambe (2016) use employee-level data from a job website to take a different approach to analyze the employment effects of LBOs. The concern with this type of study is that certain types of employees might choose to use the job website and so it is difficult to generalize the results. Nevertheless, the detailed data allow in-depth insight for those workers that use the website in their job search. They analyze the impact on duration of employment and, if an employee loses his or her job, the subsequent impact on employment duration. They find that employment spells are 6 to 8.2 percentage points longer in portfolio firms compared to control firms. In addition, for those workers that leave a portfolio firm after an LBO, their employment duration is 2.9 months shorter than those in control firms. They attribute this to post-LBO investment in IT resulting in workers’ complementary IT skills being upgraded, which in turn improves their employability.

Summary

While some studies do find that LBOs impact on employment, most find that the average effect is modest. There is some evidence of positive effects with increased employment in LBOs of private firms, divisions, and SBOs, which is consistent with an entrepreneurial perspective. In addition, the evidence concerning MBIs and IBOs suggests that job losses are more likely to be associated with deals where inside-management are not associated with the deal, suggesting outside acquirers are more likely to instigate restructuring that leads to job losses. The evidence also suggests that lower-skilled workers and white-collar workers suffer negative effects. Low-skilled job losses could be the result of automation and offshoring and white-collar job losses could be the result of LBOs downsizing corporate bureaucracy. The evidence suggests a complicated picture of the employment effects of LBOs. There is no clear evidence that there should be government intervention in the LBO market in order to protect jobs.

502Wage effects

There are fewer studies assessing the impact on wages compared to the number of employment studies (Table 26.2). The theoretical background outlined earlier has little to say on the wage effects of LBOs. Nevertheless, a key criticism of LBOs is that they create an opportunity for the new owners to suppress wages, which could be a source of improvements in operating performance.

Table 26.2      Summary of wage studies reviewed in chronological order

image

503Average pay per worker

Much work in this area makes use of data available in company reports. Most private firms will report the number of employees and the wage bill, therefore, these studies will simply assess the impact of an LBO on average pay per worker. Amess and Wright (2007) provide evidence for UK deals. They estimate that average pay growth is 0.31 of a percentage point lower in MBOs and 0.97 of a percentage point lower in MBIs. For the sample of firms used in the study, coefficient estimates indicate that average pay per employee grows by £83.70 and £231.35 less per annum for MBO and MBI firms, respectively, compared to control firms.

Bergstrom et al.’s (2007) analysis of Swedish PE-backed LBOs and Georgen et al’s (2011) analysis of UK IBOs both find no significant impact on average wage level. This is supported by Amess et al.’s (2014) UK study using techniques that account for potential selection bias to the LBO form, who find that PE-backed and non-PE-backed LBOs have no significant effect on the wage per worker over the period t−1 to t+2. In contrast, Davis et al. (2014) report that PE-backed LBOs in the US have earnings per worker 2.4% lower compared to controls two years after the deal. While Bergstrom et al. (2007) find that PE-backed LBOs have no impact on wages, they do however find a negative relationship between wage growth and the relative change in operating performance. They argue that this is indicative of wage reductions explaining post-LBO changes in performance.

The impact on workers with different characteristics

There is a body of literature that recognizes that the impact of LBOs on wages might be different for workers with different characteristics. Lichtenberg and Siegel (1990) examined the distinct wage effects for nonproduction and production workers. They found that the annual compensation for nonproduction workers fell by 5.2% over the period t−1 to t+2 around the deal. In contrast, over the same period, they find that the annual and hourly compensation per production worker is 3.6% and 2.3% higher, respectively. They argue that this is consistent with compensation being used to motivate employees rather than direct monitoring.

Antoni et al. (2015) estimate that the impact on the average employee’s wage ranges from 0.96% to 2.68%. More in-depth analysis using education and occupation reveals that the impact of LBOs on wages varies across different types of employees. Target employees with low and medium levels of education experience greater wage improvements than for those with high levels of education. Highly educated employees gain 0.07% while the additional gain for low educated and medium educated is 1.19% and 2.06%, respectively. The wage effect is different when proxy measures for occupational skills are considered. White-collar workers achieve a wage gain of about 1%, unskilled blue-collar workers receive a wage gain that is not statistically significant from this, and skilled blue-collar workers gain by an estimated 2.84%. Antoni et al. also find that the characteristics of workers for whom LBOs have a negative effect are those employees: with high tenure, who are older, and are middle managers. A positive effect for female employees is found, although this may be due to females being over-represented in the medium educated group.

Heterogeneity in employee wages after an LBO is also reported in Agrawal and Tambe (2016). They examine wage differences between those workers that have never been employed by a firm acquired by an LBO with employees that have been employed by an LBO target at some point in the sample. The rationale for this is that employees will acquire 504transferable human capital after PE-led investment in IT and so the wage effects of an LBO on an employee will persist after they have left an LBO target firm and obtained a job in another firm. Employees that were once employed in an LBO target experience a 2.5–3.5% wage gain for each unit increase in IT complementary skills. In high IT firms, such wage gains are estimated to be up to 13% higher.

Summary

The evidence suggests that the impact of LBOs on wages is fairly modest. In addition, the evidence to date is mixed. This mixed body of evidence does not strongly support the argument that LBOs lead to wage suppression but neither does it suggest that the average employee shares in post-LBO performance gains. Nevertheless, there is evidence to suggest heterogeneous wage effects across different types of employees. In particular, the evidence suggests skilled workers experience the highest wage gains.

Future research

Over the years, the evidence on employment and wage effects has grown and has become increasingly nuanced, providing depth to our understanding of the effects of LBOs on employees. Nevertheless, the evidence is largely mixed and fails to provide firm support for either positive or negative effects for employees. The most insightful research appears to assess the impacts for different types of employees. There are several areas where research on the employment and wage effects of LBOs would be useful.

First, future research on workers’ pay could examine the impact of LBOs on different pay components. The structure of pay packages impacts on risk-sharing and incentives. For instance, profit-sharing and bonus schemes provide stronger incentives to reduce employee moral hazard than a salary or wage. Could greater use of these types of pay components be a driver of improved performance after an LBO? Profit-sharing schemes could also be attractive to post-LBO owners because it means they share performance risk with employees. The wage bill will be positively correlated with firm performance. Do LBOs adopt profit-sharing schemes to reduce the new owners’ exposure to performance risk?

Second, Shleifer and Summers (1988) argue that corporate restructuring presents an opportunity for implicit labor contracts to be renegotiated. Obviously, implicit features of a labor contract are by definition impossible, or at least very difficult, to observe and measure. There are aspects of being employed that could indicate whether implicit agreements with employees have been broken or have deteriorated after an LBO. For instance, if employees become less satisfied with their work (i.e., feeling more insecure, the lack of opportunity to develop skills, and feeling less achievement in their work) and feeling more worried, depressed, and tense about work. There is increasing interest in the well-being of individuals; the impact of corporate restructuring transactions, such as an LBO, on workers well-being could be a fruitful area of research that expands our knowledge of the labor consequences beyond the narrow economic confines of having a job and how well it pays.

Third, pensions can represent an important part of a pay package. Some employees might be willing to accept lower wages in return for a better pension. Such arrangements are not typically part of an explicit employment contract; rather, they are implicit. Employer pension liabilities and employer pension contributions, however, might be an area where the LBO restructuring creates an opportunity where such an implicit contract is changed unfavorably for employees in order to generate savings that benefit LBO investors.

505Fourth, there are broader aspects of the work environment that impact on employees’ welfare. For instance, some firms will offer their employees flexi-time, job sharing, and on the job training and education, and benefits in kind such as health insurance and a car. These aspects of work are provided by employers on a voluntary basis and future research could determine whether cost-cutting after an LBO leads to a reduction in the provision of these aspects of work. In addition, there could be an assessment of changes to employees’ workload and duties along with changes to contractual status from permanent to casual.

Finally, much of the evidence provided to date uses US and UK data, although there is some evidence from other European countries. PE is a growing feature of capital markets in developing economies, such as India and China. Such markets provide an interesting context because their capital markets are generally considered less developed than those in the US and Europe. This might mean there is potential for upside gains and employment creation due to PE investment. In countries with less employment regulation, however, LBOs may be more likely to depress wages. Some markets also see PE firms with private, state, and foreign ownership operating alongside each other. It would be interesting to find out the different employment and wage effects of different PE firms.

Conclusions

This chapter reviews the agency and entrepreneurship perspectives of LBOs and outlines arguments concerning their impact on jobs and wages. The agency perspective predicts the realignment of managers’ and owners’ incentives after an LBO will result in job losses. Critics of PE firms have taken this type of argument to suggest that any gains they make could be attributable to transfers from employees. This might be in the form of job losses or the suppression of wages. An entrepreneurial perspective suggests that LBOs provide incentives for the new owners to invest in entrepreneurial growth, resulting in job creation. A weakness of the entrepreneurial perspective is that it has little to say on how an LBO impacts on wages.

Unfortunately, the evidence does not provide a clear picture of the effects of LBOs on jobs and wages for PE-backed deals. Nevertheless, there appears to be some evidence of job creation in deals that are characterized as entrepreneurial. The employee-level studies provide insightful evidence as to the gainers and losers from being employed at an LBO target. Recent studies suggest that low-skilled workers are more likely to suffer job and wage losses, while skilled workers experience wage gains. The lack of consensus in the evidence and the paucity of studies conducting employee-level analysis suggests there is scope for further research in this area.

Note

  1    The proportion of equity held by management varies depending on the size of the deal. Centre for Management Buy-Out Research data for UK deals shows that for deals valued below £10 million management hold about 60–80% of equity while for deals valued greater than £10 million the amount of equity held by management is about 25–40%. The remaining equity is held by PE firms.

References

Agrawal, A., & Tambe, P. 2016. Private equity and workers’ career paths: The role of technological change. Review of Financial Studies, 29: 2455–2489.

Akerlof, G. A. 1982. Labour contracts as partial gift exchange. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 97: 543–569.

506

Amess, K. 2003. The effect of management buyouts on firm-level technical efficiency: Evidence from a panel of UK machinery and equipment manufacturers. Journal of Industrial Economics, 51: 35–44.

Amess, K., Girma, S., & Wright, M. 2014. The wage and employment consequences of ownership change. Managerial and Decision Economics, 35: 161–171.

Amess, K., Stiebale, J., & Wright, M. 2015. The impact of private equity on firms’ patenting activity. European Economic Review, 86: 147–160.

Amess, K., & Wright, M. 2007. The wage and employment effects of leveraged buyouts in the UK. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 14: 179–195.

Amess, K., & Wright, M. 2012. Leveraged buyouts, private equity and jobs. Small Business Economics, 38: 419–430.

Antoni, M., Maug, E. G., & Obernberger, S. 2015. Private equity and human capital risk Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2602771.

Applebaum, E., & Batt, R. 2014. Private equity at work. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

Behr, P., Norden, L., & Noth, F. 2013. Financial constraints of private firms and bank lending behaviour. Journal of Banking and Finance, 37: 3472–3485.

Berger, A. N., & Udell, G. F. 1998. The economics of small business finance: The roles of private equity and debt markets in the financial growth cycle. Journal of Banking and Finance, 22: 613–673.

Bergstrom, C., Grubb, M., & Jonsson, S. 2007. The operating impact of buyouts in Sweden: A study of value creation. Journal of Private Equity, 11: 22–39.

Bernstein, S., & Sheen, A. 2016. The operational consequences of private equity buyouts: Evidence from the restaurant industry. Review of Financial Studies, 29: 2387–2418.

Boucly, Q., Sraer, D., & Thesmar, D. 2011. Growth LBOs. Journal of Financial Economics, 102: 432–453.

Bruining, H., Verwaal, E., & Peterson, B. C. 2012. Private equity and entrepreneurial management in management buy-outs. Small Business Economics, 40: 591–605.

Carpenter, R. E., & Petersen, B. C. 2002. Is the growth of small firms constrained by internal finance? Review of Economics and Statistics, 84: 298–309.

Davis, S. J., Haltiwanger, J., Handley, K., Jarmin, R., Lerner, J., & Miranda, J. 2014. Private equity, jobs, and productivity. American Economic Review, 104: 3956–3990.

Engel, D., & Stiebale, J. 2014. Private equity, investment and financial constraints: Firm-level evidence for France and the United Kingdom. Small Business Economics, 43: 197–212.

Faccio, M., & Hsu, H.-C. 2017. Politically connected private equity and employment. Journal of Finance, 72: 539–573.

Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. 1983. Agency problems and residual claims. Journal of Law & Economics, 26: 327–350.

Fox, I., & Marcus, A. 1992. The causes and consequences of leveraged management buyouts. Academy of Management Review, 17: 62–85.

Georgen, M, O’Sullivan, N., & Wood, G. 2011. Private equity takeovers and employment in the UK: Some empirical evidence. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 19: 259–275.

Georgen, M., O’Sullivan, N., & Wood, G. 2014. The employment consequences of private equity acquisitions: The case of institutional buyouts. European Economic Review, 71: 67–79.

Harris, R., Siegel, D. S., & Wright, M. 2005. Assessing the impact of management buyouts on economic efficiency: Plant-level evidence from the United Kingdom. Review of Economics and Statistics, 87: 148–153.

Hart, O. 1995. Corporate governance: some theory and implications. Economic Journal, 105: 678–689.

International Trade Union Confederation 2007. Where the house always wins: Private equity, hedge funds and the new casino capitalism. Brussels: International Trade Union Confederation.

Jensen, M. C. 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeover. American Economic Review, 76: 323–329.

Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305–360.

Kaplan, S. 1986. The effects of management buyouts on operating performance and value. Journal of Financial Economics, 24(2): 217–254.

Kaplan, S. 1989. The effects of management buyouts on operating performance and value. Journal of Financial Economics, 24: 217–254.

507

Kaplan, S., & Stromberg, P. 2009. Leveraged buyouts and private equity. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23: 121–146.

Lichtenberg, F. R., & Siegel, D. 1990. The effects of leveraged buyouts on productivity and related aspects of firm behaviour. Journal of Financial Economics, 27: 165–194.

Meuleman, M., Amess, K., Wright, M., & Scholes, L. 2009. Agency, strategic entrepreneurship, and the performance of private equity-backed buyouts. Entrepreneurship: Theory & Practice, 33: 213–239.

Shleifer, A., & Summers, L. H. 1988. Breach of trust in hostile takeovers. In A. Auerbach (Ed.), Corporate takeovers: Causes and consequences. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Smith, A. 1990. Corporate ownership structure and performance: The case of management buyouts. Journal of Financial Economics, 27: 143–164.

Stiglitz, J. E. 1987. The causes and consequences of the dependence of quality on price. Journal of Economic Literature, 25: 1–48.

Tåg, J., & Olsson, M. 2016. Private equity, layoffs, and job polarization. Journal of Labor Economics, 35: 697–754.

Thompson, S., & Wright, M. 1995. Corporate governance: The role of restructuring transactions. Economic Journal, 105: 690–703.

Williamson, O. E. 1975. Markets and hierarchies. New York: Free Press.

Williamson, O. E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press.

Wright, M., Thompson, S., & Robbie, K. 1992. Venture capital and management-led, leveraged buyouts: A European perspective. Journal of Business Venturing, 7: 47–71.

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset