Chapter 2

The Regulatory Environment

Abstract

Considerable time is devoted to discussing the prenotification and disclosure requirements of current takeover legislation and how decisions are made within the key securities law and antitrust enforcement agencies. The chapter also reviews in some detail the effectiveness of recent changes made to insider trading laws, revisions made to intellectual property guidelines, circumstances under which antitrust regulators will intervene, the impact of antitrust actions on firm value, and expanded powers granted the Committee on Foreign Investment in the US in 2018. Furthermore, the implications of the Dodd-Frank bill passed in 2010 and its subsequent revision in 2018 are discussed. Also addressed are the potential repercussions for M&As of the 2018 European Union‘s General Data Protection Regulations and the California Consumer Privacy Act. Finally, this chapter provides an overview of the labyrinth of environmental, labor, benefit, and foreign (for cross-border transactions) laws affecting M&As and recent changes to such laws.

Keywords

M&A regulations; Antitrust law; Securities law; Corporate law; Dodd-Frank bill; SEC; Securities and exchange commission; US Corrupt Practices Act; Fair disclosure; Regulation FD; Securities Exchange Act; Williams Act; Sherman Act; Clayton Act; Federal Trade Commission; Hart-Scott-Rodino; Intellectual property; Insider trading; Sarbanes-Oxley Act; Consent decrees; Enforcement efforts; Cross-border transactions; Horizontal mergers; Vertical mergers; Equity crowdfunding; Regulations; Regulatory

I am not a product of my circumstances. I am a product of my decisions.

Stephen Covey

Inside Mergers and Acquisitions: DowDuPont’s Regulatory Nightmare

Key Points: To Illustrate

  •  The daunting array of regulatory approvals multinational acquirers must obtain to complete deals in each country in which they have operations,
  •  Common concessions made by acquirers to get government consent for M&As, and
  •  The potential delay in closing due to the regulatory process.

The merger between Dow Chemical Company (Dow) and E. I. du Pont de Nemours and Company (DuPont) took nearly 2 years to complete. The new firm will be named DowDuPont Inc., with annual net sales of $73 billion, a market capitalization of more than $153 billion, and market leadership positions in three global divisions: Agriculture, Materials Science and Specialty Products.

The two mega chemical companies completed the deal on September 1, 2017 after first announcing their agreement to a merger of equals in early December 2015. Following closing, this highly complex combination must now deal simultaneously with two major challenges: achieving promised cost and revenue synergies and its planned spin-off of its three major businesses to DowDuPont shareholders. The deal took about 21 months to complete in large part because of the complex multinational regulatory review process it experienced.

The regulatory thicket through which Dow and DuPont had to navigate included the antitrust regulators in the US, the European Union, Canada, China, India, and Mexico. To gain approval in each country, the companies had to agree to concessions often involving the divestiture of some of their business units that would have dominated their markets following the merger.

In the US, the Justice Department’s Antitrust Division signed off on the transaction in June 2017, the last to do so, after the companies agreed to sell certain assets. These included DuPont’s crop protection products and Dow’s copolymers and ionomers products. The Justice Department had been reviewing the planned merger for more than a year. In order to secure approval from the European Union, both companies also were required to divest certain business units. DuPont sold off its crop protection business and associated research function to FMC Corp. Dow divested its acid copolymers and ionomers business. The European Union asked for concessions because it feared the merger would stifle competition and increase prices for farmers. Dow and DuPont are among a slew of recent mega deals in the agriculture industry that have made farmers and consumer advocates nervous.

When China granted its approval in May, the country asked that the companies divest DuPont’s assets related to pesticides and herbicides used in rice. In India, Dow and DuPont were asked by the country’s antitrust watchdog for “remedies” tailored to the market for grape fungicides and certain types of polymers. The remedies were designed to prevent the company from engaging in what the regulators considered potentially anticompetitive activities. Canada’s Competition Board gave approval subject to DuPont selling off part of its global herbicides business including R&D operations to FMC Corp. The Board also reported that Dow will sell part of its global plastics businesses to SK Global Chemical Corp. Mexico’s antitrust agency approved the merger subject to Dow selling its acid copolymers and ionomers segments. DuPont was asked to divest an insecticide plant.

Chapter Overview

In late 2017, the US Justice Department filed an antitrust lawsuit challenging Parker Hannifin Corp.’s takeover of Clarcor Inc. alleging the deal created a monopoly enabling the firm to raise prices substantially. The transaction would eliminate Parker Hannifin’s only competitor in the market for products that filter aviation fuel and represented the first such challenge under the Trump administration. In asking a federal judge to order Parker Hannifin to divest its own aviation fuel filter business or Clarcor’s, the Justice Department was attempting to restore the prior level of competition in this market.

Most deals requiring regulatory review do ultimately receive approval, although often with concessions made by the parties involved. Why do regulators find some deals acceptable and not others? This question and many others are addressed by focusing on the key elements of the regulatory process and its implications for M&As. The labyrinth of environmental, labor, benefit, and foreign laws that affect M&As is also discussed. Table 2.1 provides a summary of applicable legislation and specific regulations discussed in this chapter. A chapter review is available (including practice questions and answers) in the file folder entitled Student Study Guide contained on the companion site to this book (https://booksite.elsevier.com/9780128150757).

Table 2.1

Laws Affecting M&A
LawIntent
Federal securities laws
Securities Act (1933)Prevents the public offering of securities without a registration statement; defines minimum data reporting requirements and noncompliance penalties
Regulation DRules pertaining to exemptions from registration requirements
Regulation FDAll material disclosures of nonpublic information made by public corporations must be disclosed to the general public
Regulation CFRules pertaining to equity crowdfunding
Securities Exchange Act (1934)Established the SEC to regulate securities trading. Empowers the SEC to revoke the registration of a security if the issuer is in violation of any provision of the 1934 act
Section 13Defines content and frequency of SEC filings as well as events triggering them
Section 14Defines disclosure requirements for proxy solicitation
Section 16(a)Defines what insider trading is and who is an insider
Section 16(b)Defines investor rights with respect to insider trading
Williams Act (1968)Regulates tender offers
Section 13DDefines disclosure requirements
Sarbanes-Oxley Act (2002)Initiates reform of regulations governing financial disclosure, governance, auditing, analyst reports, and insider trading
Jumpstart Our Business Startups Act or JOBS Act (2012)Intended to reduce reporting requirements for so-called “emerging companies”
Federal antitrust laws
Sherman Act (1890)Made “restraint of trade” illegal; establishes criminal penalties for behaviors that limit competition unreasonably
Section 1Makes mergers creating monopolies illegal
Section 2Applies to firms already dominant in their served markets to prevent them from “unfairly” restraining trade
Clayton Act (1914)Outlawed such practices as price discrimination, exclusive contracts, tie-in contracts, and created civil penalties for illegally restraining trade
Celler-Kefauver Act of 1950Amended the Clayton Act to cover asset as well as stock purchases
Federal Trade Commission Act (1914)Established a federal antitrust enforcement agency; made it illegal to engage in deceptive business practices
Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvement Act (1976)Requires a waiting period before a transaction can be completed and sets regulatory data submission requirements
Title IDefines what must be filed
Title IIDefines who must file and when
Title IIIEnables state attorneys general to file triple damage suits on behalf of injured parties
Other legislation affecting M&As
Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (2010)Reforms executive compensation; introduces new hedge/private equity fund SEC registration requirements; increases Federal Reserve and SEC regulatory authority; gives the government authority to liquidate systemically risky firms; enables government regulation of consumer financial products; and makes it illegal for federal employees and regulators to engage in insider trading
Revisions to Dodd-Frank Act in 2018Increased the asset threshold from $50 billion to $250 billion for banks to be declared “systemically risky.” Banks whose assets less than $10 billion not subject to the “Volcker Rule”
State antitakeover lawsDefines conditions under which a change in corporate ownership can take place; may differ by state
State antitrust lawsSimilar to federal antitrust laws; states may sue to block mergers, even those not challenged by federal regulators
Exon-Florio Amendment to the Defense Protection Act of 1950Establishes Committee on Foreign Investment in the US (CIFIUS) to review the impact of foreign direct investment (including M&As) on national security
Foreign Investment National Security Act of 2007CIFIUS review powers expanded to include cross-border deals in energy, technology, shipping, and transportation
Foreign Investment Risk Review Modernization Act of 2018CFIUS powers amended to include review of non-controlling interests in “critical technologies”
US Foreign Corrupt Practices ActProhibits payments to foreign government officials in exchange for obtaining new business or retaining existing contracts
Industry-specific regulationsBanking, communications, railroads, defense, insurance, and public utilities
Environmental laws (federal and state)Defines disclosure requirements
Labor and benefit laws (federal and state)Defines disclosure requirements
Applicable foreign lawsCross-border transactions subject to jurisdictions of countries in which the bidder and target firms have operations

Table 2.1

Understanding Federal Securities Laws

Whenever the acquirer or target has publicly traded securities, the firms are subject to the substantial reporting requirements of the current federal securities laws.1 Passed in the 1930s, these laws reflected the loss of confidence in the securities markets following the 1929 stock market crash.

Securities Act of 1933

This legislation requires that securities offered to the public be registered with the government to protect investors by making issuers disclose all material facts regarding the security issue. Registration requires, but does not guarantee, that the facts represented in the registration statement and prospectuses are accurate. The law makes providing inaccurate or misleading statements in the sale of securities to the public punishable with a fine, imprisonment, or both. The registration process involves a description of the company’s properties and business, a description of the securities, information about management, and financial statements certified by public accountants.

Securities Exchange Act of 1934

The Securities Exchange Act extends disclosure requirements stipulated in the Securities Act of 1933 to include securities already trading (so-called seasoned or secondary issues) on the national exchanges. The Act also established the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), whose purpose is to protect investors from fraud by requiring full and accurate financial disclosure by firms offering stocks, bonds, and other securities to the public. In 1964, coverage was expanded to include securities traded on the Over-the-Counter (OTC) Market. The act also covers proxy solicitations (i.e., mailings to shareholders requesting their vote on a particular issue) by a company or shareholders. The 2010 Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protections Act (Dodd-Frank Act) strengthened the SEC enforcement powers by allowing the commission to impose financial penalties against any person, rather than against just entities.

Reporting Requirements

Companies having to file periodic reports with the SEC are those for which any of the following are true. The firm has assets of more than $10 million and whose securities are held by more than 499 shareholders; it is listed on any of the major US or international stock exchanges; or its shares are quoted on the OTC Bulletin Board. Even if both parties to a transaction are privately owned, an M&A transaction is subject to federal securities laws if a portion of the purchase price is going to be financed by an initial public offering of securities.

Section 13: Periodic Reports

Form 10 K documents the firm’s financial activities during the preceding year. The four key financial statements that must be included are the income statement, the balance sheet, the statement of retained earnings, and the statement of cash flows. Form 10 K also includes a relatively detailed description of the business, the markets served, major events and their impact on the business, key competitors, and competitive market conditions. Form 10Q is a highly succinct quarterly update of such information. An 8 K is a public declaration of material events that could be of importance to shareholders or to the SEC. If an acquisition or divestiture is deemed significant,2 an 8 K must be submitted to the SEC within 15 days of the event. Form 8 K describes the assets acquired or disposed, the type and amount of consideration (i.e., payment) given or received, and the identity of the person (or persons) for whom the assets were acquired. In an acquisition, Form 8K also must identify who is providing the funds used to finance the purchase and the financial statements of the acquired business. For this reason, the vast majority of M&As are announced immediately following the signing of a definitive agreement.3

Section 14: Proxy Solicitations

Where proxy contests deal with corporate control, the act requires materials containing the names and interests of all participants to be filed with the SEC in advance of voting. If the deal involves either acquirer or target shareholder approval, any materials distributed to shareholders must conform to the SEC rules for proxy materials.

Insider Trading Regulations

Insider trading involves individuals who buy or sell securities based on knowledge that is not available to the public. Historically, insider trading has been covered under the Securities and Exchange Act of 1934. Section 16(a) of the act defines “insiders” as corporate officers, directors, and any person owning 10% or more of any class of securities of a company. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOA) of 2002 amended Section 16(a) of the 1934 act by requiring that insiders disclose changes in ownership within 2 business days of the transaction, with the SEC posting the filing on the Internet within 1 business day after the filing is received.

The SEC is responsible for investigating insider trading. Regulation 10b-5, issued by the SEC, prohibits the commission of fraud in relation to securities transactions. Regulation 14e-3 prohibits trading securities in connection with a tender offer (i.e., an offer to buy securities) based on information that is not publicly available. Individuals found guilty of engaging in insider trading may be subject to substantial penalties and forfeiture of any profits.4 In 2010, the Dodd-Frank Act granted the Commodity Futures Trading Commission authority to investigate insider trading in commodities used in interstate commerce and made it illegal for federal employees to engage in insider trading. The Act also allows the SEC to compensate those providing original information on insider trading activities (so-called whistleblowers) up to 30% of the damages assessed in the successful prosecution of insider trading cases.

The effectiveness of insider trading legislation is limited, due to the difficulty in defining such activity. While the rate at which insiders buy target firm shares slows prior to takeover announcement dates, they reduce the pace at which they sell shares by even more, such that their actual holdings increase.5 Such activity is most common in deals where there is less uncertainty about their completion, that is, friendly deals and those with a single bidder. The magnitude of the increase in the dollar value of insider share holdings is about 50% higher than levels normally found in the 6 months prior to announcement dates.6

In an effort to limit litigation, corporations voluntarily restrict when insiders can trade in the firm’s securities. Corporate policies specify certain time periods during which insiders are allowed to trade their stock. During so-called blackout periods, insiders are forbidden to trade their shares without corporate approval. Firms often permit those designated as insiders to trade during short time periods after the quarterly earnings announcement dates, with many requiring their insiders to obtain prior approval even when they trade during the allowed periods. However, despite these restrictions, employees interested in engaging in such practices continue to find ways to circumvent such restrictions.7

Hedge funds by their nature must be adept to exploit differences in what is believed to be the fair value of a stock and the actual price. To be nimble in decision-making, they may exploit networks which can give them an information edge over their competitors. Researchers have documented that hedge funds tend to take sizeable positions in the shares of firms in which there has been a significant amount of inside information leaked to the public.8

While most insider trading deals with using nonpublic information to profit from equities, there is also evidence that insiders use nonpublic information to profit from trading in bonds. Bonds issued by firms that are a takeover target often are subject to abnormally large trading volumes just prior to the announcement of the deal, with their prices increasing (decreasing) before they are acquired by firms with better (worse) credit ratings.9

Longer sentences may eventually deter insider trading. According to Reuters, those engaged in insider trading are receiving stiffer sentences. Those convicted received an average sentence of 17.3 months for the 5 years ending in 2012 compared to an average of 13.1 months during the prior 5-year period. The average length of sentences could continue to increase due to stiffer sentencing guidelines.

On December 7, 2016, the US Supreme Court ruled that prosecutors in insider trading cases do not always have to show that money or something of value changed hands. The Supreme Court concluded that offering information to a relative is the same as trading on the information by the tipster followed by a gift of the proceeds generated. Simply proving a tipster and trader were related was enough to initiate a lawsuit alleging insider trading.

The more difficult issues pertaining to cases about trading among friends and professional acquaintances were addressed in an August 22, 2017 ruling by the Second Circuit Court of Appeals in Manhattan. The ruling substantially broadened the application of insider trading laws concluding that the government needs to prove only that a gift of inside information to anybody knowing they are going to trade on that information is illegal. Prior to this ruling the government had to prove a meaningful close relationship between the tipster and the recipient of significant, nonpublic information in cases involving people who were not relatives.

Why do some insiders continue to use nonpublic information despite the potential cost (e.g., fines, jail time and reputational damage), the increased likelihood of being convicted, and the relatively modest amount often received from such trading? The answer may reflect the level of wealth and income of those engaging in such activities. That is, less wealthy insiders are more likely to trade on private information because the dollar amounts received often are sufficient to compensate for the potential costs, while wealthier insiders find the relatively modest returns insufficient to offset the costs if their trading activities are discovered.10

Jumpstart Our Business Startups Act (JOBS Act)

Signed into law on April 5, 2012, the JOBS Act mandated changes to Rule 506 of the SEC’s Regulation D (Reg D) which governed private placement exemptions. These exemptions allow for qualifying firms to obtain financing more rapidly and to avoid the cost of full registration of their security issues. The reforms took effect on September 23, 2013.

Prior to June 16, 2015, equity crowdfunding11 (subsumed under Reg D) was limited to individuals satisfying certain net worth and income levels (i.e., accredited investors) and had to be conducted through a licensed broker-dealer. As a result of the JOBS Act, both accredited and non-accredited investors were allowed to invest in private companies through licensed broker-dealers or internet sites registered with the SEC. At the end of 2017, there were 17 such sites registered with the SEC.

The JOBS Act is intended to reduce reporting requirements for so-called “emerging companies,” those with less than $1 billion in annual revenue in their most recent fiscal year and fewer than 2000 shareholders. For qualifying firms, the SEC requires only 2 years of audited financial statements in its IPO registration documents, a less detailed disclosure of executive compensation, and no requirement for Sarbanes Oxley Act (SOA) Section 404(b), which deals with internal controls and financial reporting.

The allowance for lighter disclosure requirements is justified in part on the notion that investors using the internet will pick the best investments reflecting the “wisdom of crowds.” There is reason to be skeptical that small investors will be protected despite having access to limited information because they often are poorly diversified, subject to a “herd” mentality, and often lack sufficient sophistication.

The JOBS Act may have contributed to increasing US IPO activity, especially among small firms. The majority of the increase cannot be explained by improving stock market or industry conditions. It seems that the new legislation has facilitated access to public markets for emerging firms seeking additional financing, “cash out” opportunities for founding investors, or to become acquisition targets.12

SEC Enforcement Effectiveness

Despite all the media fanfare that often accompanies SEC investigations, some question the SEC’s effectiveness in protecting the public from securities fraud. The SEC’s Division of Enforcement looks into possible violations of federal securities laws, and prosecutes the Commission’s civil suits in federal courts as well as its administrative proceedings. In civil suits, the Commission seeks injunctions or orders prohibiting certain behavior. Anyone violating an injunction is subject to fines or imprisonment for contempt.

Data reported annually by the Commission suggests that over time it has been highly effective as both the number of enforcement actions (i.e., those taken to ensure compliance with prevailing laws) undertaken and the amount of fines assessed has tended to increase significantly over time. However, empirical evidence suggests that SEC data may be seriously flawed due to double and even triple counting some of its cases and overstating the actual dollar amount of fines collected. Adjusting for these distortions, enforcement activity between 2002 and 2014 appears to have been relatively steady.13

The Williams Act: Regulation of Tender Offers

Passed in 1968, the Williams Act consists of a series of amendments to the Securities Act of 1934 intended to protect target shareholders from fast takeovers in which they do not have enough time to assess adequately an acquirer’s offer. This protection was achieved by requiring more disclosure by the bidding company, establishing a minimum period during which a tender offer must remain open and authorizing targets to sue bidding firms. The disclosure requirements of the Williams Act apply to anyone, including the target, asking shareholders to accept or reject a takeover bid. The major sections of the Williams Act as they affect M&As are in Sections 13(D) and 14(D). The Williams Act requirements apply to all types of tender offers, including those negotiated with the target firm (i.e., negotiated or friendly tender offers), those undertaken by a firm to repurchase its own stock (i.e., self-tender offers), and those that are unwanted by the target firm (i.e., hostile tender offers).14

Sections 13(D) and 13(G): Ownership Disclosure Requirements

Section 13(D) of the Williams Act is intended to regulate “substantial share” or large acquisitions and provides an early warning for a target’s shareholders and management of a pending bid. Any person or firm acquiring 5% or more of the stock of a public firm must file a Schedule 13(D) with the SEC within 10 days of reaching that percentage threshold. Section 13(D) also requires that derivatives, such as options, warrants, or rights convertible into shares within 60 days, must be included in determining whether the threshold has been reached. Schedule 13(D) requires the inclusion of the identities of the acquirer, their occupation and associations, sources of financing, and the purpose of the acquisition. If the purpose of buying the stock is to take control of the target firm, the acquirer must reveal its business plan for the target. The plans could include the breakup of the firm, suspending dividends, a recapitalization of the firm, the intention to merge it with another firm, or simply the accumulation for investment purposes only.

Under Section 13(G), any stock accumulated by related parties, such as affiliates, brokers, or investment bankers working on behalf of the person or firm, are counted toward the 5% threshold. This prevents an acquirer from avoiding filing by accumulating more than 5% of the target’s stock through a series of related parties. Institutional investors, such as registered brokers and dealers, banks, and insurance companies, can file a Schedule 13(G)—a shortened version of Schedule 13(D)—if the securities were acquired in the normal course of business.

The permitted reporting delay under Section 13(D) of up to 10 days allows for potential abuse of the disclosure requirement. In late 2010, activist hedge fund investor William Ackman and real estate company Vornado Realty Trust surprised Wall Street when they disclosed that they had acquired nearly 27% of mega-retailer J.C. Penney’s outstanding shares. Once the investors exceeded the 5% reporting threshold, they rapidly accumulated tens of millions of shares during the ensuing 10-day period, driving J.C. Penney’s share price up 45%. In mid-2014, William Ackman again made headlines by having amassed a 9.7% stake in drug company Allergan becoming its largest shareholder before having to publicly disclose this information. The investment was undertaken as part of an effort to acquire Allergan by competitor Valeant Pharmaceuticals and raised questions about whether Ackman had violated insider trading laws by benefitting from his knowledge of the takeover attempt before it was made public. To improve transparency to the investing public, Britain, Hong Kong, and Germany require investors to disclose their positions in 4 days or less.

Section 14(D): Rules Governing the Tender Offer Process

Although Section 14(D) of the Williams Act relates to public tender offers only, it applies to acquisitions of any size. The 5% notification threshold also applies.

  • Obligations of the acquirer. An acquirer must disclose its intentions, business plans, and any agreements between the acquirer and the target firm in a Schedule 14(D)-1. The schedule is called a tender offer statement. The commencement date of the tender offer is defined as the date on which the tender offer is published, advertised, or submitted to the target. Schedule 14(D)-1 must contain the identity of the target company and the type of securities involved; the identity of the person, partnership, syndicate, or corporation that is filing; and any past contracts between the bidder and the target company. The schedule also must include the source of the funds used to finance the tender offer, its purpose, and any other information material to the transaction.
  • Obligations of the target firm. The management of the target company cannot advise its shareholders how to respond to a tender offer until it has filed a Schedule 14(D)-9 with the SEC within 10 days after the tender offer’s start date. This schedule is called a tender offer solicitation/recommendation statement.
  • Shareholder rights: 14(D)-4 to 14(D)-7. The tender offer must remain open for a minimum of 20 trading days. The acquiring firm must accept all shares that are tendered during this period. The firm making the tender offer may get an extension of the 20-day period if it believes that there is a better chance of getting the shares it needs. The firm must purchase the shares tendered at the offer price, at least on a pro rata or proportional basis, unless the firm does not receive the total number of shares it requested under the tender offer. The tender offer also may be contingent on the approval of the Department of Justice (DoJ) and the Federal Trade Commission (FTC). Shareholders can withdraw shares tendered previously as long as the tender offer remains open. The law also requires that when a new bid for the target is made from another party, the target firm’s shareholders must have an additional 10 days to consider the bid.
  • The “best price” rule: 14(D)-10. To avoid discrimination, the “best price” rule requires all shareholders holding the same class of security be paid the same price in a tender offer. If a bidder increases what it is offering to pay for the remaining target firm shares, it must pay the higher price to those who have already tendered their shares.

Court rulings in the mid-1990s indicated that executive compensation such as golden parachutes, retention bonuses, and accelerated vesting rights triggered whenever a change in control occurred should be counted as part of the compensation they received for their shares. These rulings significantly reduced the use of tender offers, due to concerns that all shareholders would have to receive payment for their shares comparable to what executives had received following a change in control. The “best price” rule was clarified on October 18, 2006, to exclude executive compensation following a change in control from the price paid for their shares. The rule changes make it clear that the “best price” rule applies only to the consideration (i.e., cash, securities, or both) offered and paid for securities tendered by shareholders.15 This clarification contributed to the recovery in the use of tender offers in recent years. Having fallen to 3.2% of total deals in 2006, tender offers accounted for about one-fifth of deals in recent years.16

The Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002

The SOA was signed in the wake of the egregious scandals at such corporate giants as Enron, MCI WorldCom, ImClone, Qwest, Adelphia, and Tyco and has implications ranging from financial disclosure to auditing practices to corporate governance. Section 302 of the act requires quarterly certification of financial statements and disclosure controls and procedures for CEOs and CFOs. Section 404 requires most public companies to certify annually that their internal control system is operating successfully and to report material weaknesses in internal controls to analysts when making earnings forecasts.17 The legislation, in concert with new listing requirements at public stock exchanges, requires a greater number of directors on the board who do not work for the company (i.e., so-called independent directors). The Act also requires board audit committees to have at least one financial expert, while the full committee must review financial statements every quarter after the CEO and chief financial officer certify them. The SOA also provides for greater transparency, or visibility into a firm’s financial statements and greater accountability. However, the flagrant practices of some financial service firms (e.g., AIG, Bear Stearns, and Lehman Brothers) in recent years cast doubt on how effective the SOA has been in achieving its transparency and accountability objectives.

Empirical studies of the SOA’s effectiveness give mixed results. As noted in a number of studies (see Chapter 13), there is growing evidence that the monitoring costs imposed by Sarbanes-Oxley have been a factor in many small firms’ going private since the introduction of the legislation.18 The overall costs of corporate boards soared post-SOA due to sharply higher director compensation. However, shareholders of large firms that are required to overhaul their existing governance systems under Sarbanes-Oxley may in some cases benefit as new shareholder protections are put in place. Moreover, the run-up in target share prices before they are publicly announced has decreased significantly since the SOA’s introduction, perhaps reflecting improved accountability and regulatory oversight of bidder managers and boards involved in deals.19

In some instances, the SOA’s requirements appear to be redundant. New York Stock Exchange listing requirements far exceed SOA’s auditor-independence requirements. Companies must have board audit committees consisting of at least three independent directors and a written charter describing its responsibilities in detail. Moreover, the majority of all board members must be independent, and non-management directors must meet periodically without management. Board compensation and nominating committees must consist of independent directors. Shareholders must be able to vote on all stock option plans.

The SOA also created a quasi-public oversight agency, the Public Company Accounting Oversight Board (PCAOB). The PCAOB is charged with registering auditors, defining specific processes and procedures for compliance audits, quality control, and enforcing compliance with specific SOA mandates.

Fair Disclosure

On August 7, 2018, entrepreneurial icon and Tesla Inc. (Tesla) Chairman and CEO Elon Musk used Twitter to announce “Am considering taking Tesla private at $420 (per share). Funding secured.”20 Once again showing the power on social media to move markets, the firm’s stock immediately soared. But did he violate US Securities and Exchange Commission rules?

He did not violate SEC regulations by using social media but he could be accused of stock manipulation if his statement was not true, particularly about the funding for such a deal being in place. Known as the Reed Hastings Rule, the SEC determined using social media as a means of disclosing material information appropriate under certain conditions after Netflix CEO Reed Hastings posted on Facebook in 2012 that views on his firm’s video streaming service “had exceeded 1 billion hours for the first time.” The SEC declared social media “perfectly acceptable” as long as investors are alerted and access is not restricted. What raised eyebrows was the veracity of Musk’s claim about having funding for such a deal. The concern is that he might have violated the SEC’s Fair Disclosure Rule.

In late September, the SEC initiated a lawsuit against Musk for alleged “false and misleading” statements that could have prevented him from running any public company. On September 29, 2018, Musk settled with the SEC by stepping down as chairman of Tesla for 3 years (but remaining as chief executive) and paying a fine of $20 million. In addition, Tesla agreed to hire several new independent board members and to establish a new committee of directors and create controls to oversee Musk’s public communications.

The US Securities and Exchange Commission adopted Regulation FD (Fair Disclosure) on August 15, 2000 to address concerns about the selective release of information by publicly traded firms. Regulation FD requires that a publicly traded firm that discloses material nonpublic information to certain parties, such as stock analysts and individual shareholders, must release that information to the general public.

Critics warned that less information about a firm’s share price would be provided by managers concerned about litigation. In fact, there are indications that there has been an increase in voluntary disclosure. However, the greater availability of information may have done little to dampen earnings’ “surprises” and to lower stock price volatility. Studies provide conflicting results, with one study reporting an increase in share price volatility and another showing no change following the implementation of Regulation FD.21

Consistent with the trend toward increased voluntary disclosure of information, the fraction of US acquirers disclosing synergy estimates when announcing a deal has increased from 7% in 1995 to 27% of total transactions in 2008, with much of the increase coming since the introduction of Regulation FD. Some researchers argue that public disclosure of synergy can help the acquirer communicate the potential value of the deal to investors lacking information available to the firm’s board and management, enabling investors to make more informed decisions. In particular, synergy disclosure can result in significantly higher acquirer announcement date financial returns by allaying investor fears that the offer price is excessive.22 Others contend that disclosing such information is self-serving, since it helps the acquirer’s board and management gain shareholder support for the transaction.23

Recent evidence suggests that acquirers may use press releases to manipulate deals in other ways. That is, acquirers in stock deals increase the number of stories after the start of merger negotiations but before the public announcement that an agreement had been reached. This media blitz may be an effort to generate a temporary increase in their share price to reduce the number of acquirer shares that must be issued for each target share outstanding. This minimizes potential dilution of acquirer shareholders.24 For example, assume the target is to receive $100 per share in terms of acquirer stock, valued at $50 per share at the time of the agreement. Therefore, the acquirer would have to issue two shares of its stock for each acquirer share. However, if the acquirer’s stock price increases to $105 per share, only 0.9524 acquirer shares ($100/$105) would have to be issued for each target share.

About one-fifth of US acquirers reveal to the public their intentions to make acquisitions when they announce the issuance of new debt or equity, frequently well in advance of an M&A announcement. Such firms often raise more money than needed to complete the subsequent acquisition. This suggests that the announcement of intent is largely designed to justify raising more money than necessary to complete any subsequent deal and to mask how the excess funds will actually be used.25

Understanding Antitrust Legislation

Federal antitrust laws exist to prevent individual corporations from assuming so much market power that they can limit their output and raise prices without concern for any significant competitor reaction. The DoJ and the FTC have the primary responsibility for enforcing federal antitrust laws. The challenge for regulators is to apply prevailing laws in such a way as to discourage monopolistic practices without reducing gains in operational efficiency that may accompany business combinations.

National laws usually do not affect firms outside their domestic political boundaries. There are two exceptions: antitrust laws and laws applying to the bribery of foreign government officials.26 Outside the United States, antitrust laws are described as competition or merger control laws, which are intended to minimize anticompetitive behavior. The European Union antitrust regulators were able to thwart the attempted takeover of Honeywell by General Electric—two US corporations with operations in the European Union. Remarkably, this occurred following the approval of the proposed takeover by US antitrust authorities. In 2014, European antitrust authorities blocked United Parcel Services’s bid to acquire Dutch shipping company TNT because of concerns about reduced competition in the continent-wide delivery of small packages. The other exception, the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act, is discussed later in this chapter.

The Sherman Act

Passed in 1890, the Sherman Act makes illegal all contracts, combinations, and conspiracies that restrain trade “unreasonably.” Examples include agreements to fix prices, rig bids, allocate customers among competitors, or monopolize any part of interstate commerce. Section I of the Sherman Act prohibits new business combinations resulting in monopolies or in a significant concentration of pricing power in a single firm. Section II applies to firms that already are dominant in their targeted markets. The act applies to all transactions and businesses involved in interstate commerce or, if the activities are local, all transactions and business “affecting” interstate commerce. Most states have comparable statutes.

The Clayton Act

Passed in 1914, the Clayton Act was created to outlaw certain practices not prohibited by the Sherman Act and to help government stop a monopoly before it developed. Section 5 of the act made price discrimination between customers illegal, unless it could be justified by cost savings associated with bulk purchases. Tying of contracts—in which a firm refuses to sell certain important products to a customer unless the customer agrees to buy other products from the firm—also was prohibited. Section 7 prohibits one company from buying the stock of another company if their combination results in reduced competition. Interlocking directorates also were made illegal when the directors were on the boards of competing firms.

Unlike the Sherman Act, which contains criminal penalties, the Clayton Act is a civil statute. The Clayton Act allows private parties that were injured by an antitrust violation to sue in federal court for three times their actual damages to encourage private lawsuits. Such lawsuits augment public antitrust law enforcement resources. If the plaintiff wins, the costs must be borne by the party that violated the prevailing antitrust law, in addition to the criminal penalties imposed under the Sherman Act. Public antitrust regulators can encourage private antitrust lawsuits by signaling the government’s commitment to fostering competition. To curb anticompetitive abuses, the signal must be highly visible and potentially costly to violators of antitrust laws.27

Acquirers soon learned how to circumvent the original statutes of the Clayton Act of 1914, which applied to the purchase of stock. They simply would acquire the assets, rather than the stock, of a target firm. Under the Celler-Kefauver Act of 1950, the Clayton Act was amended to give the FTC the power to prohibit asset as well as stock purchases.

The Federal Trade Commission Act of 1914

This act created the FTC, consisting of five full-time commissioners appointed by the president for a 7-year term. The commissioners have a support staff of economists, lawyers, and accountants to assist in the enforcement of antitrust laws.

The Hart-Scott-Rodino (HSR) Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976

Acquisitions involving companies of a specific size cannot be completed until certain information is supplied to the federal government and a specified waiting period has elapsed. The premerger notification allows the FTC and the DoJ time to challenge acquisitions believed to be anticompetitive before they are completed. Once the merger has taken place, it is often difficult to break it up.

Parties proposing a deal meeting certain size requirements file with both the FTC and DoJ, but only one antitrust agency will review the proposed merger. Since both the FTC and the DoJ share jurisdiction over transactions requiring review, deals are assigned on a case-by-case basis depending on which agency has more expertise with the industry involved and resources available to conduct the review. This is known as the “clearance process.” The reviewing agency may issue an “early termination” of the waiting period or allow the waiting period to elapse, in either case allowing the deal to close.

Failing to get regulatory approval can be costly in terms of having to pay target shareholders termination fees if negotiated as part of the contract, demands on company resources in performing target due diligence, legal and consulting fees, management distraction, etc. One study finds that the failure to get antitrust regulatory approval results in a reduction in acquirer shareholder value of about 2.8%. Therefore, lobbying before deal announcements to take advantage of political connections makes sense and such efforts are frequently associated with more favorable review outcomes, especially in horizontal deals.28

Alternatively, the regulators can request additional information in a so-called “second request.” At the end of the process, the reviewing agency may let the waiting period expire or decide to challenge the deal by filing a preliminary injunction in federal court pending an administrative trial on the merits of the case. A challenge stops the parties from closing the deal. If challenged, the deal may still be approved as long as the filing parties are willing to make changes to the proposed merger acceptable to regulators. Fig. 2.1 illustrates the premerger notification and review process, and Table 2.2 provides a summary of 2018 prenotification filing requirements.

Fig. 2.1
Fig. 2.1 Prenotification and review process.

Table 2.2

Regulatory Prenotification Filing Requirements Effective February 28, 2018
Williams ActHart-Scott-Rodino Act
Required filing

1. Schedule 13(D) within 10 days of acquiring 5% stock ownership in another firm

2. Ownership includes stock held by affiliates or agents of the bidder

3. Schedule 14(D)-1 for tender offers

4. Disclosure required even if 5% accumulation not followed by a tender offer

HSR filing is necessary when:

1. Size-of-transaction test: The buyer purchases assets or securities >$84.4 million

2. Size-of-parties testa: Buyer or seller has annual net sales or assets ≥$168.8 million and any other party has net sales or assets ≥$16.9 million

3. If the acquisition value >$337.6 million, a filing is required regardless of whether (2) is met

Thresholds in (1)–(3) are adjusted annually by the increase in gross domestic product
File with whomSchedule 13(D)

1. Premerger Notification Office of the Federal Trade Commission

2. Director of Operations of the DoJ Antitrust Division

1. 6 copies to SEC

2. 1 copy via registered mail to target’s executive office

3. 1 copy via registered mail to each public exchange on which target stock is traded

Schedule 14(D)-1

1. 10 copies to SEC

2. 1 copy hand-delivered to target’s executive offices

3. 1 copy hand-delivered to other bidders

4. 1 copy mailed to each public exchange on which the target stock is traded (each exchange also must be phoned)

Time period

1. Tender offers must stay open a minimum of 20 business days

2. Begins on date of publication, advertisement, or submission of materials to target

3. Unless the tender offer has been closed, shareholders may withdraw tendered shares up to 60 days after the initial offer

1. Review/waiting period: 30 days (15 days for cash tender offers)

2. Target must file within 15 days of bidder’s filing

3. Period begins for all cash offers when bidder files; for cash/stock bids, period begins when both bidder and target have filed

4. Regulators can request a 20-day extension

Table 2.2

a The “size of parties” test measures the size of the “ultimate parent entity” of the buyer and seller. The ultimate parent entity is the entity that controls the buyer and seller and is not itself controlled by anyone else.

Title I: What Must Be Filed?

Title I of the act gives the DoJ the power to request internal corporate records if it suspects potential antitrust violations. Information requirements include background data on the “ultimate parent entity”29 of the acquiring and target parents, a description of the deal, and all background studies relating to the transaction.

Title II: Who Must File and When?

Title II addresses the conditions under which filings must take place. In 2018, to comply with the size-of-transaction test, transactions in which the buyer purchases voting securities or assets valued in excess of $84.4 million must be reported under the HSR Act. However, according to the size-of-parties (a reference to the acquirer and target firms) test, transactions valued at less than this figure may still require filing if the acquirer or the target firm has annual net sales or total assets of at least $168.8 million and the other party has annual net sales or total assets of at least $16.9 million. These thresholds are adjusted upward by the annual rate of increase in gross domestic product. A filing is required if the transaction value exceeds $337.6 million without regard to whether the size-of-person test is met.

Bidding firms must execute an HSR filing at the same time they make an offer to a target firm. The target also is required to file within 15 days following the bidder’s filing. Filings consist of information on the operations of the two companies and their financial statements. The waiting period begins when both the acquirer and target have filed. The FTC or the DoJ may request a 20-day extension of the waiting period for transactions involving securities and 10 days for cash tender offers. If the acquiring firm believes there is little likelihood of anticompetitive effects, it can request early termination. In practice, only about 20% of transactions require HSR filings; of these only about 4% are challenged by the regulators.30

If the regulatory authorities suspect anticompetitive effects, they will file a lawsuit to obtain a court injunction to prevent completion of the proposed transaction. Although it is rare for the bidder or the target to contest the lawsuit because of the expense involved and even rarer for the government to lose, it does happen.31 If fully litigated, a government lawsuit can result in huge legal expenses and a significant cost in management time. Even if the FTC’s lawsuit is overturned, the benefits of the merger often have disappeared by the time the lawsuit has been decided. Potential customers and suppliers are less likely to sign lengthy contracts with the target firm during the period of trial. New investment in the target is limited, and employees and communities where the target’s operations are located are subject to uncertainty. As such, both regulators and acquirers try to avoid litigation.

How Does HSR Affect State Antitrust Regulators?

Title III expands the powers of state attorneys general to initiate triple damage suits on behalf of individuals in their states injured by violations of the antitrust laws.

Procedural Rules

A DoJ antitrust lawsuit is adjudicated in the federal courts. When the FTC initiates the action, it is heard before an administrative law judge at the FTC, whose ruling is subject to review by FTC commissioners. Criminal actions are reserved for the DoJ, which may seek fines or imprisonment for violators. Individuals and companies also may file antitrust lawsuits. The FTC reviews complaints that have been recommended by its staff and approved by the commission. The commission then votes whether to accept or reject the hearing examiner’s findings. The decision of the commission then can be appealed in the federal circuit courts. As an alternative to litigation, a company may seek to negotiate a voluntary settlement of its differences with the FTC. Such settlements usually are negotiated during the review process and are called consent decrees. The FTC then files a complaint in the federal court along with the proposed consent decree. The federal court judge routinely approves the consent decree.

The Consent Decree

A typical consent decree may consist of both structural and behavioral remedies. Structural remedies generally require the party or parties seeking regulatory approval to change the structure of their businesses. This usually involves the sale of assets or businesses in areas where they compete directly. Structural remedies differ from behavioral remedies, which are designed to regulate the future conduct of the relevant party or parties (for example, by regulating the prices which a party may charge). Behavioral remedies may require significant monitoring by regulators to ensure compliance.

In mid-2018, German chemical giant Bayer agreed to a structural remedy involving the sale of agricultural businesses and assets valued at $9 billion to chemical company BASF to get US regulatory approval to complete its $66 billion takeover of US based Monsanto. In the largest antitrust related divestiture on record, the US regulators reasoned that the sell-off offered customers a viable alternative to Bayer for certain agricultural chemicals. Similarly, the Justice Department’s approval of the $69 billion merger between CVS Health and health insurer Aetna in late 2018 required Aetna to sell its private Medicare drug plans. Regulators believed this action would provide consumers with more choices and would help restrain the potential pricing power of the combined businesses. As a condition of approving the January 2011 acquisition of NBC Universal (NBCU) by Comcast, Comcast agreed to several behavioral remedies that would impact its future conduct of the combined businesses. Comcast committed to arbitrate disputes with other cable systems concerning their access to NBCU’s cable channels.

If a potential acquisition is likely to be challenged by the regulatory authorities, an acquirer may seek to negotiate a consent decree in advance of the deal. In the absence of a consent decree, a buyer often requires that an agreement of purchase and sale includes a provision allowing the acquirer to back out of the transaction if it is challenged by the FTC or the DoJ on antitrust grounds. Consent decrees do seem to limit potential increases in business pricing power following a merger by creating viable competitors.32

Antitrust Guidelines for Horizontal Mergers

Understanding an industry begins with analyzing its market structure. Market structure may be defined in terms of the number of firms in an industry; their concentration, cost, demand, and technological conditions; and ease of entry and exit. Intended to clarify the provisions of the Sherman and Clayton acts, the DoJ issued in 1968 largely quantitative guidelines, presented in terms of specific market share percentages and concentration ratios, indicating the types of M&As it would oppose. Concentration ratios were defined in terms of the market shares of the industry’s top four or eight firms. The guidelines have been revised to reflect the role of both quantitative and qualitative data. Qualitative data include factors such as the enhanced efficiency resulting from a combination of firms, the financial viability of potential merger candidates, and the ability of US firms to compete globally.

In 1992, both the FTC and the DoJ announced a new set of guidelines indicating that they would challenge mergers creating or enhancing market power, even if there are measurable efficiency benefits. Market power is defined as a situation in which the combined firms will be able to profitably maintain prices above competitive levels for a significant period. The 1992 guidelines were revised in 1997 to reflect the regulatory authorities’ willingness to recognize that improvements in efficiency over the long term could more than offset the effects of increases in market power. On August 19, 2010, the guidelines were updated to give regulators more leeway to challenge mergers than previously. However, they also raised the thresholds for determining if a merger would cause anticompetitive concentration. The new guidelines closely resemble the European Union’s antitrust guidelines. In general, horizontal mergers are most likely to be challenged by regulators. Vertical mergers—those involving customer-supplier relationships—are considered much less likely to result in anticompetitive effects, unless they deprive other firms access to an important resource.

As part of the review process, regulators consider customers and the prospect for price discrimination, market definition, market share and concentration, unilateral effects, coordinated effects, ease of entry, realized efficiencies, potential for business failure, and partial acquisitions. These factors are considered next.

Targeted Customers and the Potential for Price Discrimination

Price discrimination occurs when sellers can improve profits by raising prices to some targeted customers but not to others. For such discrimination to exist there must be evidence that certain customers are charged higher prices even though the cost of doing business with them is no higher than selling to other customers, who are charged lower prices. Furthermore, customers charged higher prices must have few alternative sources of supply.

Market Definition

Markets are defined by regulators solely in terms of the customers’ ability and willingness to substitute one product for another in response to a price increase. The market may be geographically defined, with scope limited by such factors as transportation costs, tariff and nontariff barriers, exchange rate volatility, and so on.

Market Share and Concentration

The number of firms in a market and their respective shares determine market concentration. Such ratios measure how much of the total output of an industry is produced by the “n” largest firms in the industry. To account for the distribution of firm size, the FTC measures concentration using the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI), which is calculated by summing the squares of the market shares for each firm competing in the market. For example, a market consisting of five firms with market shares of 30%, 25%, 20%, 15%, and 10%, respectively, would have an HHI of 2250 (302 + 252 + 202 + 152 + 102). Note that an industry consisting of five competitors with market shares of 70%, 10%, 5%, 5%, and 5%, respectively, will have a much higher HHI score of 5075, because the process of squaring the market shares gives the greatest weight to the firm with the largest market shares.33

The HHI ranges from 10,000 for an almost pure monopoly to approximately 0 in the case of a highly competitive market. The index gives more weight to the market shares of larger firms to reflect their relatively greater pricing power. The FTC scoring system described in Fig. 2.2 is one factor in determining if the FTC will challenge a proposed deal.

Fig. 2.2
Fig. 2.2 FTC actions at various market share concentration levels. HHI, Herfindahl-Hirschman Index. FTC Merger Guidelines, www.ftc.gov.

Almost one third of industries in the United States in 2015 were considered highly concentrated under current federal antitrust standards. This compares to approximately one fourth in 1996.34 In many cases, this increased concentration is driven by technological innovation and the need for consolidation in the face of intensifying global competition. Mergers offer economies of scale and scope that increase efficiency and innovation35 and in some instances preserve jobs at firms too weak to remain competitive on their own. Reflecting these factors, there appears to be little evidence of a widespread or systematic decline in the degree of competition in the US despite the increase in market concentration during the last 20 years. While in the aggregate this may be true, at the individual industry level, the impact of an increase in competition can be ambiguous: it can be a result of intensified competition (as argued above) or contribute to increased pricing power for the remaining firms in the industry.36

Unilateral Effects

A merger between two firms selling differentiated products may reduce competition by enabling the merged firms to profit by unilaterally raising the price of one or both products above the premerger level. Furthermore, a merger between competitors prevents buyers from negotiating lower prices by playing one seller against the other. Finally, in markets involving undifferentiated products, a firm, having merged with a large competitor, may restrict output in order to raise prices.

Coordinated Effects

After a merger with a competitor, a firm may coordinate its output and pricing decisions with the remaining firms in the industry. Such actions could include a simple understanding of what a firm would do or not do under certain circumstances. If the firm with dominant market share was to reduce output, others may follow suit, with the intent of raising product prices.

Ease of Entry

Ease of entry is defined as entry that would be timely, likely to occur, and sufficient to counter the competitive effects of a combination of firms that temporarily increases market concentration. Barriers to entry—such as proprietary technology or knowledge, patents, government regulations, exclusive ownership of natural resources, or huge investment requirements—can limit the number of new competitors that enter a market. Excessive entry barriers may hinder innovation because of a reduced need to do so due to the limited threat of competition. However, defining what is excessive is highly subjective.

Efficiencies

Increases in efficiency resulting from M&As can enhance the combined firms’ ability to compete and result in lower prices, improved quality, better service, or innovation. However, efficiencies are difficult to measure and verify, because they will be realized only after the merger has taken place. An example of verifiable efficiency improvements would be a reduction in the average fixed cost per unit of output due to economies of scale.

Alternative to Imminent Failure

Regulators also consider the likelihood that a firm would fail if not allowed to merge with another firm. The regulators must weigh the potential cost of the failing firm, such as a loss of jobs, against any potential increase in market power resulting from a merger.

Partial Acquisitions

Regulators may also review acquisitions of minority positions involving competing firms if it is determined that the partial acquisition results in the effective control of the target firm. A partial acquisition can lessen competition by giving the acquirer the ability to influence the competitive conduct of the target firm, in that the acquirer may have the right to appoint members of the board of directors. Furthermore, the minority investment also may blunt competition if the acquirer gains access to nonpublicly available competitive information.

Antitrust Guidelines for Vertical Mergers

In supply chains,37 many firms pursue vertical integration with their upstream (i.e., distributors) or downstream (i.e., suppliers) partners to realize competitive advantages.38 Supply chains contain multiple levels with several firms competing at each level. Vertical mergers may become a concern if an acquisition by a supplier of a customer prevents the supplier’s competitors from having access to the customer. Alternatively, the acquisition by a customer of a supplier could become a concern if it prevents the customer’s competitors from having access to the supplier.

Recent theoretical work expands the circumstances under which vertical mergers can encourage anticompetitive conditions. Vertical mergers, so goes the argument, increase profits from collusion and therefore the incentive to collude. They create cost differences between integrated and non-integrated competitors. The vertically integrated firms are able to improve their total profit margins because they are buying downstream inputs at cost, while the non-integrated firms pay prices for the same inputs which include a profit margin. The integrated firm can set prices by implicitly threatening aggressive price discounting, as they in theory have higher profit margins, if non-integrated firms do not follow suit. By offering the same prices as the integrated competitor, the non-integrated firm can enjoy higher profits. Thus, vertical integration can offer significant benefits by colluding.39

While rare, vertical mergers are more likely to result in regulatory review when firms dominant in their respective markets integrate vertically. On November 20, 2017, AT&T’s $85 billion planned takeover of Time Warner Inc. was blocked by the US Justice Department, which expressed concern that the combination would lead to higher prices for traditional pay-TV and limit the expansion of low cost streaming services threatening AT&T’s DirecTV business.40 The proposed combination is considered a vertical merger, because AT&T’s primary business is providing phone service, while Time Warner’s focus is on TV and movie production. The merger would combine the nation’s second-largest phone company and largest pay-TV provider with Time Warner’s assets including HBO, TBS, TNT, Cartoon Network and Warner Bros. The Justice Department sought to block the merger even though it had approved a similar merger between Comcast and NBCUniversal in 2011 arguing that the AT&T-Time Warner deal was three times larger. On June 12, 2018, a federal judge dismissed the Justice Department’s case and approved the AT&T’s takeover of Time Warner, without attaching any conditions to his ruling.

Antitrust Guidelines for Collaborative Efforts

Collaborative efforts are horizontal agreements among competitors such as joint ventures and strategic alliances. Regulators are less likely to block a collaborative effort if (i) the participants have continued to compete through independent operations or through other collaborative efforts; (ii) the financial interest in the effort by each participant is relatively small; (iii) each participant’s ability to control the effort is limited; (iv) effective safeguards prevent information sharing; and (v) the duration of the collaborative effort is short.

Revisions to Intellectual Property Guidelines

On January 12, 2017, US government regulators issued revised antitrust guidelines pertaining to intellectual property. Ownership of intellectual property is subject to the guidelines applicable to other forms of property. However, the new guidelines incorporate recent Supreme Court rulings that a patent does not necessarily confer market power on the patent holder. That is, simply refusing to convey the use of such property to competitors generally does not violate antitrust law. Also, prices charged for granting others the right to use intellectual property are subject to the “rule of reason.”41

When Are Antitrust Regulators Most Likely to Intervene?

The likelihood of antitrust intervention in horizontal mergers is less when foreign import competition is high, an industry is difficult to monopolize due to low entry barriers, existing competitors have the capacity to increase supply, and mergers are motivated by efficiency gains. Regulatory authorities are more likely to intervene when market concentration is high.

Antitrust enforcement has not been consistent with the stated aim of protecting consumers as the regulatory agencies do not systematically select cases which appear to be harmful to consumers in general or customers of local businesses. Regulators can be influenced to intervene on behalf of competitors who tend to benefit from preventing a rival from consummating a merger. Local and less specialized competitors who are most likely to face pressure from gains in efficiency resulting from a merger are the ones most likely to benefit.42

Trends in Enforcement Efforts

Enforcement efforts ebb and flow with changes in presidential administrations and political and economic philosophies. During much of the decade ending in 2010, business combinations among direct competitors tended to be less restrictive as they were viewed as a means of achieving greater operating efficiency. In recent years, enforcement efforts have become more aggressive, especially in such concentrated industries as telecommunications, airlines, and media.

Just the threat of regulatory intervention appears to have been a major factor in deterring the proposed tie-ups between Sprint and T-Mobile and 21st Century Fox and Time Warner in 2014. In neither instance, did the Justice Department or the Federal Communications Commission (FCC) announce a formal position on either deal. The Sprint-T-Mobile deal would have reduced the number of wireless competitors from four to three and the Fox-Time Warner combination would have joined the two largest movie studios and two of the five largest television producers. In 2015 and 2016, other potential tie-ups that were abandoned due to regulatory investigations included the Comcast/Time Warner Cable, Applied Materials/Tokyo Electron, GE/Electrolux, and Bumble Bee/Chicken of the Sea deals.

The impact of failing to receive regulatory approval can be very costly for acquirers. In mid-2016, oil services providers Halliburton and Baker Hughes called off their planned $35 billion merger. The decision was made after a lengthy regulatory review in which the US Justice Department decided to block the deal. Halliburton had to pay Baker Hughes a $3.5 billion termination fee, one of the largest on record, to exit the merger agreement. The amount was included in the merger agreement to reassure Baker Hughes that Halliburton expected the deal to close.

How Business Platform Strategies Complicate Antitrust Enforcement

A business platform strategy is one in which a firm creates value by expediting transactions between consumers and producers. To do so, businesses create large, scalable communities/networks of users that can be accessed on demand. Examples include Facebook, Apple, Google/YouTube, Alibaba, and Uber. Successful platforms build strong barriers to entry for potential competitors in the form of extensive networks or installed user bases and operate at a scale that results in their having extremely low user acquisition and retention costs. See Chapter 4 for a more detailed discussion of this subject.

Current antitrust law does not easily address market dominance when it develops in this manner. The current law focuses on how a proposed M&A impacts output and prices and in turn consumer welfare to determine if it is anticompetitive. But that framework does not apply easily to businesses that grow through platform strategies.

Amazon.com is the premier example of how a successful platform strategy contributes to market dominance. Amazon has become the global hub of online retail commerce. It has done so by building a highly scalable infrastructure to support a growing volume of users attracted by the convenience of having access to the vast array of products offered at prices that may be below cost. This has the effect of increasing scale to drive down infrastructure expenses per dollar of revenue. Not only can this infrastructure be used to dominate specific lines of business but also related lines of business. Amazon is now in a variety of seemingly unrelated lines of business ranging from a delivery and logistics network and an auction house to a major book publisher, a TV and film producer, and hardware manufacturer to a leading supplier of cloud services, fashion design, and grocery business.

The common element is that each line of business generates data on consumer and business buying behaviors which can be used to determine pricing strategies, achieve optimal inventory management, and to anticipate future product offerings in various markets. A recent illustration of the value of this data is Amazon’s foray into the grocery business involving the acquisition of Whole Foods in late 2016. Amazon plans to use its database of consumer information to determine the number and type of products and in what quantities to offer products at various store locations.

The end result of successful platform strategies is that they tend to concentrate market power in a relatively few businesses. Once a business has a dominant position in a market, it may be able to stifle innovation of new products that could threaten their own product offering and to raise prices with relative ease. Note that de facto price increases can be achieved by lowering product quality without actually raising selling prices. Firms competing on the basis of achieving platform dominance in multiple markets may choose to vertically integrate by owning valuable content, which can be sold across markets. Such firms also can restrict competitor access to this content.

If platform strategies do indeed lead to natural monopolies,43 regulators are faced with few alternatives. One option is to let online competitors govern the market place. Antitrust regulators can help sustain competition by limiting the extent to which a firm’s platform is used in other markets, to lower the threshold for proving predatory pricing, and banning vertical integration by those firms operating platform businesses.44 Another option is for regulators to approve business combinations involving platform businesses that increase efficiency through economies of scale to achieve savings that can be passed onto customers. Regulators can then treat such businesses as utilities and regulate what they can charge their customers and the services they may offer.

Impact of Antitrust Actions on Firm Value

Empirical studies of regulatory announcements to investigate potential antitrust violations on firm value confirm that initially the share prices of the firms involved drop. However, they recover quickly if the concessions required to gain approval are seen by investors as minimal.45 Other studies show that the impact of legislative changes or regulatory policy reform on a firm’s share price varies by industry. For example, financial services firms tend to be more regulated than non-financial firms with regulators often having more enforcement discretion. Research seems to indicate that investors view new merger control legislation establishing clearer guidelines as positive, because such laws reduce the discretion (and implicitly the perceived arbitrariness) given to regulators.46

The Impact of Politics on Gaining Regulatory Approval

M&As involve a highly regulated process; as such, they are susceptible to political influence. At the federal level, the FTC and DoJ may be influenced by political concerns. Pressures often are even greater at the local level. Concerned about re-election and possibly about career opportunities once out of public office, local politicians can see contributions dry up from corporations, their reputations suffer, and constituents subject to job losses when an important local business is acquired. As a result, firms contributing to politicians are actually less likely to be acquired and, if acquired, more likely to command higher takeover premiums since their political connections may make their growth opportunities more valuable. Moreover, the elapsed time between the announcement date and closing may be lengthy because of politically motivated intervention by states attorneys general on antitrust grounds or alleged securities violations.47

M&A Implications of the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (Including 2018 Revisions)

Comprehensive in scope, the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010 (the Act) substantially changed federal regulation of financial services firms as well as some nonfinancial public companies. The Act’s objectives included restoring public confidence in the financial system and preventing future financial crises that threaten the viability of financial markets. Its provisions range from giving shareholders a say on executive compensation to greater transparency in the derivatives markets to new powers granted to the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) to liquidate financial firms whose failure would threaten the US financial system. Some argue that efforts to make the largest banks less risky should be focused on divesting the investment banking and non-commercial banking lines of business.48

While the implications of the legislation are far reaching, the focus in this book is on those aspects of the Act impacting corporate governance directly; the environment in which M&As and other restructuring activities take place; and participants in the restructuring process. The Act’s provisions (and 2018 revisions) having the greatest impact on M&As and restructuring are summarized in Table 2.3 as follows: governance and executive compensation, systemic regulation and emergency powers, capital markets, and financial institutions.

Table 2.3

Selected Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act Provisions (Including 2018 Revisions)
ProvisionRequirements
Governance and executive compensationa
Say-on-payIn a nonbinding vote on the board, shareholders may vote on executive compensation packages every 2 or 3 years
Say on golden parachutesProxy statements seeking shareholder approval of acquisitions, mergers, or sale of substantially all of the company’s assets must disclose any agreements with executive officers of the target or acquiring firm with regard to present, deferred, or contingent compensation
Institutional investor disclosureInstitutional managers (e.g., mutual funds, pension funds) must disclose annually their positions on pay and on golden parachutes voting
ClawbacksPublic companies are required to develop and disclose mechanisms for recovering incentive-based compensation paid during the 3 years prior to earnings restatements
Broker discretionary votingPublic stock exchanges are required to prohibit brokers from voting shares without direction from owners in the election of directors, executive compensation, or any other significant matter as determined by the SEC
Compensation committee independenceSEC to define rules requiring stock exchanges to prohibit listing any issuer that does not comply with independence requirements governing compensation of committee members and consultants
Systemic regulation and emergency powers
Financial Stability Oversight CouncilTo mitigate systemic risk, the Council, consisting of 10 voting members and chaired by the Secretary of the Treasury, monitors US financial markets to identify domestic or foreign banks and some nonbank firms whose default or bankruptcy would risk the financial stability of the United States
New Federal Reserve (Fed) Bank and Nonbank Holding Company supervision requirementsBank and nonbank holding companies with consolidated assets exceeding $250 billion must:

 Submit plans for their rapid and orderly dissolution in the event of failure

 Provide periodic reports about the nature of their credit exposure

 Limit their credit exposure to any unaffiliated company to 25% of its capital

 Conduct semiannual “stress tests” to determine capital adequacy

 Provide advance notice of intent to purchase voting shares in financial services firms

Limitations on leverageFor bank holding companies whose assets exceed $250 billion, the Fed may require the firm to maintain a debt-to-equity ratio of no more than 15-to-1
Limits on sizeThe size of any single bank cannot exceed 10% of deposits nationwide. The limitation does not apply for mergers involving troubled banks
Capital requirementsBank capital requirements are to be left to the regulatory agencies and should reflect the perceived risk of bank or nonbank institutions
Savings and loan regulationsFed gains supervisory authority over all savings and loan holding companies and their subsidiaries
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)The FDIC may guarantee obligations of solvent insured depository institutions if the Fed and the Systemic Risk Council determine that financial markets are illiquid (i.e., investors cannot sell assets without incurring a significant loss)
Orderly Liquidation AuthorityThe FDIC may seize and liquidate a financial services firm, whose failure threatens the financial stability of the United States, to ensure the speedy disposition of the firm’s assets and to ensure that losses are borne by shareholders and bondholders while losses of public funds are limitedb
Capital markets
Office of Credit RatingsProposes rules for internal controls, independence, transparency, and penalties for poor performance, making it easier for investors to sue for “unrealistic” ratings. Office to conduct annual audits of rating agencies
SecuritizationIssuers of asset-backed securities must retain an interest of at least 5% of the collateral underlying any security sold to third parties
Hedge and Private Equity Fund RegistrationAdvisers to private equity and hedge funds with $100 million or more in assets under management must register with the SEC as investment advisers; those with less than $100 million will be subject to state registration. Registered advisors to provide reports and be subject to periodic examinations
Clearing and trading of over-the-counter (OTC) derivativesCommodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) and SEC to mandate central clearing of certain OTC derivatives on a central exchange and the real-time public reporting of volume and pricing data as well as the parties to the transaction
Financial institutions
Volcker RuleProhibits insured depository institutions and their holding companies from buying and selling securities with their own money (so-called proprietary trading) or sponsoring or investing in hedge funds or private equity funds. Underwriting and market-making activities are exempt. Proprietary trading may occur outside the United States as long as the bank does not own or control the entity. Sponsoring private funds is defined as serving as a general partner or in some way gaining control of such funds. Banks whose assets are less than $10 billion are not subject to the Volcker Rule
Consumer Financial Protection BureauCreates an agency to write rules governing all financial institutions offering consumer financial products, including banks, mortgage lenders, and credit card companies as well as “pay day” lenders. The authority applies to banks and credit unions with assets over $10 billion and all mortgage-related businesses. While institutions with less than $10 billion will have to comply, they will be supervised by their current regulators
Federal Insurance OfficeMonitors all aspects of the insurance industry (other than health insurance and long-term care), coordinates international insurance matters, consults with states regarding insurance issues of national importance, and recommends insurers that should be treated as systemically important

Table 2.3

a See Chapter 3 for more details.

b See Chapter 17 for more details.

On May 24, 2018, President Trump signed into law revisions to the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010 intended to free smaller banks from being classified as “too big to fail” in an effort to revitalize bank lending. Smaller banks will no longer be subject to the more stringent capital and liquidity requirements, leverage and lending limits, mandatory risk committees and resolution plans, and annual stress tests applied to large banks. Specifically, the new legislation raised to $250 billion the asset threshold for banks to be subject to the more stringent regulatory oversight as “systemically important financial institutions.”49 The new law also exempts small banks with assets under $10 billion from the Volcker rule ban on proprietary trading. Banks between $100 billion and $250 billion in assets will still face periodic stress tests, but will be exempted from other tougher standards 18 months from the date of the bill’s enactment on May 24, 2018. The legislation will leave fewer than 10 US banks subject to the most restrictive federal oversight.

M&A activity among banks has been subdued since the financial market meltdown in 2008–2009 as regulators have prevented deals that made banks bigger and more complex. Since restrictions on smaller banks have been relaxed, further bank consolidation among the nation’s approximate 5600 banks may be likely. Immediately following the announcement of the new legislation, Fifth Third Bancorp announced it had reached an agreement to buy MB Financial for $4.7 billion. Other factors contributing to future bank mergers include the widening of the difference between bank lending rates and their cost of funds and expected continued growth in the US economy.

M&A Implications of Data Protection Regulations

Effective May 24, 2018, the European Union’s 28 countries adopted new data protection rules known as the General Data Protection Regulation (GDPR) enabling consumers to reduce their information footprint left when browsing the internet. How? By allowing consumers access to their personal data held by firms and giving them the option to have it deleted. Businesses must more clearly detail how personal data is being handled and face limitations on how such data can be used in marketing. The GDPR applies to firms processing personal data with a presence in the EU, as well as those outside the EU offering goods or services to EU residents or monitoring their behavior. The GDPR will have an impact beyond EU borders as Brazil, Japan, and South Korea are expected to follow the EU’s lead, with the EU ready to limit access to its market if countries do not comply with its standards.

In contrast, the US currently lacks a single data protection law comparable to the GDPR. Rather, US privacy legislation has been adopted on sector by sector basis.50 Unlike the EU, the US relies on a combination of legislation, regulation, and self-regulation, rather than simply government regulation. Why? Free speech is guaranteed explicitly in the US Constitution while privacy is only an implicit right as interpreted by the US Supreme Court.

The ad hoc regulatory approach in the US could soon change as the California Consumer Privacy Act (CCPA) of 2018 takes effect on January 1, 2020. And the California law could become a model for similar laws in other states. The CCPA gives consumers the right to request data businesses have collected on them, to object to their data being sold, to receive their data in a portable format, and the right to ask businesses to delete their personal data. Personal data is defined in broad categories such as biometric data, psychometric information, browsing and search history, and geolocation data. Rather than having a patchwork of individual state laws, firms using consumer data extensively argue that data protection is better achieved through a federal law rather than state by state which can result in inconsistent regulation.

Critics argue the CCPA risks damaging everything from retailers’ customer loyalty programs to data gathering at Google, Facebook, and Apple. By giving consumers the right to opt out of data sharing and the sale of personal data, retailer loyalty programs offering discounts to members could be threatened as retailers cannot discriminate against those that opt out versus those who do not. Personalized marketing campaigns and location based apps also could be at risk. The law could hit data brokers such as Acxiom and Experian which collect consumer information for resale particularly hard.

The proliferation of data protection laws creates new challenges for firms engaged in cross-border as well as domestic takeovers. Non-compliant acquirers must incur the expense of installing the systems and processes to gain regulatory approval and to avoid hefty fines. Data related liabilities can arise years after a target firm has been acquired necessitating more comprehensive and intrusive due diligence to minimize potential liabilities. (See Chapter 5 for further discussion of this issue.) For global tech firms such as Facebook and Google, a patchwork of inconsistent data privacy laws requires modifications of their systems to account for the idiosyncrasies of each country’s laws. The same applies to firms wishing to do business in multiple states within the US. Finally, increasing limitations of how personal data is used for various types of marketing programs could limit future profitability of target firms whose business model is dependent on its customers’ data.

State Regulations Affecting Mergers and Acquisitions

In the US, laws affecting takeovers often differ from one among states, complicating being in compliance with all such laws when deals involve multiple state jurisdictions. These are discussed next.

State Antitakeover Laws

Supporters of laws providing protection to target firm shareholders argue that such laws improve deal efficiency, protect minority shareholders, and ultimately generate higher returns for target shareholders. The source of the efficiency gains in the takeover process comes from the likelihood of competing offers and more time for allowing shareholders to consider such bids. Critics argue that such laws increase barriers to takeovers and heighten the potential for management entrenchment. They also argue that such laws lead to less efficiency because of higher transaction costs or overbidding by the acquirer due to increased competition among bidders. Others argue that increased protection is a zero sum game benefitting target shareholders at the expense of acquirer shareholders by transferring gains from bidders to targets and leaving total synergies unchanged.51

With 66% of all Fortune 500 companies as of 2017 incorporated in Delaware, the state’s corporate law has a substantial influence on publicly traded firms. The next most popular state is Nevada with 15%. Delaware corporate law generally defers to the judgment of business managers and board directors in accordance with the so-called “business judgment rule.” This rule acknowledges that the daily operation of a business is inherently risky and controversial; and, as such, states that the board of directors should be allowed to make decisions without fear of being prosecuted. The rule further assumes that it is unfair to expect those managing a company to make the right decisions all the time. If the courts believe a board acted rationally, there should be no legal repercussions against managers and directors. The major exception is in change of control situations. Here, managers are subject to an enhanced business judgment test. This requires a target board to show there are reasonable grounds to believe that a danger to corporate viability exists and that the adoption of defensive measures is reasonable. While Delaware law is the norm for many companies, firms incorporated in other states often are subject to corporate law that may differ from Delaware law. What follows is a discussion of commonalities across the states.

States regulate corporate charters. Corporate charters define the powers of the firm and the rights and responsibilities of its shareholders, boards of directors, and managers. However, states are not allowed to pass any laws that impose restrictions on interstate commerce or conflict in any way with federal laws. State laws affecting M&As tend to apply only to firms incorporated in the state or that conduct a substantial amount of their business within the state. These laws often contain fair price provisions, requiring that all target shareholders of a successful tender offer receive the same price as those tendering their shares. In an attempt to prevent highly leveraged transactions, some state laws include business combination provisions, which may specifically rule out the sale of the target’s assets for a specific period.52

Other common characteristics of state antitakeover laws include cash-out and control-share provisions. Cash-out provisions require a bidder whose purchases of stock exceed a stipulated amount to buy the remainder of the target stock on the same terms granted those shareholders whose stock was purchased at an earlier date. By forcing acquiring firms to purchase 100% of the stock, potential bidders lacking substantial financial resources are eliminated from bidding. Share-control provisions require that a bidder obtains prior approval from shareholders possessing large blocks of target stock once the bidder’s purchases of stock exceed some threshold level. The latter provision can be troublesome to an acquiring company when the holders of the large blocks of stock tend to support target management.

Antitakeover laws helping to insulate firms from takeover threats can benefit some stakeholders more than others. When shareholder and management interests are misaligned, shareholders may demand greater financial reporting conservatism (transparency) to limit managerial efforts to increase compensation and to make value destroying acquisitions. This benefits debtholders more than shareholders by curtailing excessive dividends to shareholders thereby reducing the potential for financial distress and eventual default.53

State Antitrust and Securities Laws

State laws are often similar to federal laws. Under federal law, states have the right to sue to block mergers, even if the DoJ or FTC does not challenge them. State “blue sky” laws are designed to protect individuals from investing in fraudulent security offerings. State restrictions can be more onerous than federal ones.

Restrictions on Direct Investment in the United States

The Committee on Foreign Investment in the United States (CFIUS) operates under the authority granted by Congress in the Exon-Florio amendment (Section 721 of the Defense Production Act of 1950). CFIUS includes representatives from many government agencies to ensure that all national security issues are considered in the review of foreign acquisitions of US businesses. The president can block the acquisition of a US corporation based on recommendations made by CFIUS if there is credible evidence that the foreign entity might take action that threatens national security. In 2007, CFIUS was amended under the Foreign Investment National Security Act to cover critical infrastructure such as cross-border transactions involving energy, technology, shipping, and transportation.

Effective August 13, 2018, the Foreign Investment Risk Review Modernization Act expanded CIFIUS’s review authority beyond those in which foreign investors had a controlling interest in a US business. Now, CIFIUS’s jurisdiction covers noncontrolling deals including “critical technologies” in industries such as defense, energy, telecommunications, and financial services and deals involving “sensitive personal data” on US citizens. Such data includes financial, insurance, and health care information.

The new legislation was prompted by complaints that foreign entities were using joint ventures with US firms or minority interests in such ventures to gain access to technology and proprietary information critical to US national security. It covers foreign entities owning a minority position in an acquirer that buys a controlling or minority interest in certain US firms. The statute also gives CFIUS the authority to initiate its own investigations instead of waiting for a buyer to seek approval.

In late 2017, the Trump administration acted on a recommendation by CFIUS and blocked a mainland Chinese backed investor from acquiring Lattice Semiconductor Corp on national security grounds. This was only the fourth time in the last quarter century that a US president stopped a foreign takeover of a US firm for this reason. In early 2018, CFIUS recommended against the sale of US based global payment service MoneyGram to China’s Alibaba affiliate Ant Financial (and the Trump administration agreed) over concerns about how personal data about US citizens would be used. Also, in 2018, the Trump administration blocked Singapore-based semiconductor manufacturer Broadcom from acquiring US based Qualcom, a leader in the development of 5G networks. The administration argued that the takeover could result in a reduction in Qualcom’s R&D investment in such networks, ceding the future development of this technology to Chinese firms.

The US Foreign Corrupt Practices Act

The Foreign Corrupt Practices Act of 1977 prohibits individuals, firms, and foreign subsidiaries of US firms from paying anything of value to foreign government officials in exchange for obtaining new business or retaining existing contracts. Even though many nations have laws prohibiting bribery of public officials, enforcement tends to be lax. Of the 38 countries that signed the 1997 Anti-Bribery Convention of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, more than one-half of the signatories have little or no enforcement mechanisms for preventing the bribery of foreign officials, according to a 2010 study by Transparency International. The US law permits “facilitation payments” to foreign government officials if relatively small amounts of money are required to expedite goods through foreign custom inspections or to gain approval for exports. Such payments are considered legal according to US law and the laws of countries in which such payments are considered routine.54

Specific Industry Regulation

In addition to the DoJ and the FTC, a variety of other agencies monitor activities (including M&As) in certain industries, such as commercial banking, railroads, defense, and cable TV.

Banking

Currently, three agencies review banking mergers. The Office of the Comptroller of the Currency has responsibility for transactions in which the acquirer is a national bank. The FDIC oversees mergers where the acquiring bank or the bank resulting from combining the acquirer and the target will be a federally insured state-chartered bank that operates outside the Federal Reserve System. The third agency is the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (the Fed). It has the authority to regulate mergers in which the acquirer or the resulting bank will be a state bank that is also a member of the Federal Reserve System.

The Dodd-Frank legislation eliminated the Office of Thrift Supervision and transferred the responsibility for regulating savings and loan associations, credit unions, and savings banks (collectively referred to as thrift institutions) to other regulators. Specifically, the Fed will supervise savings and loan holding companies and their subsidiaries; the FDIC will gain supervisory authority of all state savings banks; and the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency will supervise all federal savings banks.

M&A transactions involving financial institutions resulting in substantial additional leverage or in increased industry concentration will also come under the scrutiny of the Financial Stability Oversight Council created by the Dodd-Frank Act to monitor systemic risk. The council is empowered, among other things, to limit bank holding companies with $50 billion or more in assets or a nonbank financial company that is regulated by the Federal Reserve from merging, acquiring, or consolidating with another firm. The council may require the holding company to divest certain assets if the company is deemed to constitute a threat to the financial stability of US financial markets. Under the new legislation, the size of any single bank or nonbank cannot exceed 10% of deposits nationwide. However, this constraint may be relaxed for mergers involving failing banks.

Communications

The FCC is charged with regulating interstate and international communication by radio, television, wire, satellite, and cable. The Commission is responsible for the enforcement of such legislation as the Telecommunications Act of 1996 intended to reduce regulation while promoting lower prices and higher quality services.

One of the FCC’s first major actions under the Trump Administration was to relax media ownership restrictions allowing TV broadcasters to own newspapers in the same market and two of the top four stations in a city. The new rules implemented on November 15, 2017 could lead to mergers among broadcasters, who have long argued that consolidation was necessary to compete with cable and internet companies for local advertising dollars.

On December 15, 2017, the FCC rescinded the so-called “net neutrality rules” that were introduced in early 2015. The rescission enables internet broadband providers, such as AT&T, Comcast, and Verizon, to determine what content they can provide and at what price. The providers can now block or slow down data transmission speeds and seek payments in exchange for faster access on their internet networks. The FCC argued that state and local governments cannot create their own net neutrality rules since internet services crossed state lines and were subject to the so-called “commerce clause.”55 Supporters of the net neutrality rules such as Google’s parent Alphabet Inc. and Facebook Inc. contend that eliminating the rules would stifle internet innovation. At the time of this writing, it is unclear how the rescission of the net neutrality regulations at the federal level will impact internet users as California enacted legislation in late 2018 preventing broadband and wireless companies from altering data transmission speeds for different internet users. The US Justice Department, arguing that the move was unconstitutional, sued the state laying the groundwork for a potentially lengthy court battle.

Railroads

The Surface Transportation Board (STB), the successor to the Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC), governs mergers of railroads. Under the ICC Termination Act of 1995, the STB determines if a merger should be approved by assessing the impact on public transportation, the areas currently served by the carriers involved in the proposed transaction, and the burden of the total fixed charges resulting from completing the transaction.

Defense

During the 1990s, the US defense industry underwent consolidation, consistent with the Department of Defense’s (DoD’s) philosophy that it is preferable to have three or four highly viable defense contractors than a dozen weaker firms. Although defense industry mergers are technically subject to current antitrust regulations, the DoJ and FTC have assumed a secondary role to the DoD. Efforts by a foreign entity to acquire national security-related assets also must be reviewed by the Council on Foreign Investment in the United States.

Other Regulated Industries

Historically, the insurance industry was regulated largely at the state level. Under the Dodd-Frank Act, the Federal Insurance Office was created within the US Treasury to monitor all non-healthcare-related aspects of the insurance industry. As a “systemic” regulator, its approval will be required for all acquisitions of insurance companies whose size and interlocking business relationships could have repercussions on the US financial system. The acquisition of more than 10% of a US airline’s shares outstanding is subject to approval of the Federal Aviation Administration. Public utilities are highly regulated at the state level. Like insurance companies, their acquisition requires state government approval.

Environmental Laws

Failure to comply adequately with environmental laws can result in enormous potential liabilities to all parties involved in a transaction. These laws require full disclosure of the existence of hazardous materials and the extent to which they are being released into the environment. Such laws include the Clean Water Act (1974), the Toxic Substances Control Act of 1978, the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act (1976), and the Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation, and Liability Act (Superfund) of 1980. Additional reporting requirements were imposed in 1986 with the passage of the Emergency Planning and Community Right to Know Act (EPCRA). In addition to EPCRA, several states also passed “right-to-know” laws such as California’s Proposition 65.

Labor and Benefit Laws

A diligent buyer also must ensure that the target is in compliance with the labyrinth of labor and benefit laws. These laws govern such areas as employment discrimination, immigration law, sexual harassment, age discrimination, drug testing, and wage and hour laws. Labor and benefit laws include the Family Medical Leave Act, the Americans with Disabilities Act, and the Worker Adjustment and Retraining Notification Act (WARN). WARN governs notification before plant closings and requirements to retrain workers.

Employee benefit plans frequently represent one of the biggest areas of liability to a buyer. The greatest liabilities often are found in defined pension benefit plans, postretirement medical plans, life insurance benefits, and deferred compensation plans. Such liabilities arise when the reserve shown on the seller’s balance sheet does not accurately indicate the true extent of the future liability. The potential liability from improperly structured benefit plans grows with each new round of legislation, starting with the passage of the Employee Retirement Income and Security Act of 1974. Laws affecting employee retirement and pensions were strengthened by additional legislation, including the Multi-Employer Pension Plan Amendments Act of 1980, the Retirement Equity Act of 1984, the Single Employer Pension Plan Amendments Act of 1986, the Tax Reform Act of 1986, and the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation acts of 1987, 1989, 1990, and 1993. Buyers and sellers also must be aware of the Unemployment Compensation Act of 1992, the Retirement Protection Act of 1994, and Statements 87, 88, and 106 of the Financial Accounting Standards Board.56

The Pension Protection Act of 2006 places a potentially increasing burden on acquirers of targets with underfunded pension plans. The legislation requires employers with defined benefit plans to make sufficient contributions to meet a 100% funding target and erase funding shortfalls over 7 years. Furthermore, the legislation requires employers with so-called “at-risk” plans to accelerate contributions. At-risk plans are those whose pension fund assets cover less than 70% of future pension obligations.

Cross-Border Transactions

Expanding global trade and capital flows (including cross-border M&As) has led to stricter national merger policies.57 Transactions involving firms in different countries are complicated by having to deal with multiple regulatory jurisdictions in specific countries or regions such as the European Union. More antitrust agencies mean more international scrutiny, potentially conflicting philosophies, and substantially longer delays in completing business combinations.

These factors can impose significant costs to acquirer and target shareholders. For example, there is evidence that European Union intervention in M&A deals during the two decades ending in 2010 reduced the combined US acquirer and target firms’ shareholder value by about $8 billion on or about the announcement date that a proposed deal would be subject to European regulatory review. The loss of shareholder value reflects the cost of legal compliance and information disclosure, restructuring the current business operation due to the antitrust remedies requested by European regulators, greater uncertainty that the deal would not close, and potential delay or loss of synergistic benefits resulting from the merger.58

International agreements have been reached in an attempt to rationalize the global regulatory process. For example, changes in European antitrust laws in 2013 are among the most recent and far-reaching revisions affecting cross-border deals. The review process, outlined in Article 101 of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU), which prohibits anticompetitive practices in 27 countries, has been greatly simplified. Certain types of agreements, such as technology transfers, between firms whose combined market share is less than 20% between competitors and less than 30% between non-competitors are exempt from TFEU review.

Such agreements are only as effective as each country’s willingness to stand by their commitments. Despite warnings from the European Union’s Internal Market regulators about the risk of protectionism and the potential incompatibility with EU treaties, the French government intervened in late 2014 in a bidding war to acquire French engineering firm Alstrom between US-based multinational General Electric and a combined bid by Germany’s Siemens and Japan’s Mitsubishi. Having built France’s power grid and high-speed TGV trains, Alstrom was viewed as an important strategic asset by the French government. GE eventually won the day by agreeing to the French government owning a 20% stake in the business. Furthermore, GE committed to increasing employment at the Alstrom operations in France. This type of government intervention can be abused. For example, in 2005, the French government declared dairy maker Danone a strategically important company to shield it from a possible takeover by US-based PepsiCo.

When regulations differ among countries, not only is the cost of takeovers affected but also the pattern of M&As as businesses engage in “regulatory arbitrage.” Firms may be encouraged to acquire targets in countries with less stringent antitrust, environmental and labor laws than those prevailing in their own countries. There is empirical evidence that the investors of firms in countries with stronger regulations are rewarded when such firms acquire targets in countries with comparatively benign regulations.59

Some Things to Remember

Current laws require that securities offered to the public must be registered with the government and that target firm shareholders receive enough information and time to assess the value of an acquirer’s offer. Federal antitrust laws exist to prevent individual corporations from assuming too much market power. Numerous state regulations affect M&As such as state antitakeover and antitrust laws. A number of industries are also subject to regulatory approval at the federal and state levels. Finally, gaining regulatory approval in cross-border transactions can be nightmarish because of the potential for the inconsistent application of antitrust laws, reporting requirements, fee structures, and legal jurisdictions.

Chapter Discussion Questions

  1. 2.1 What factors do US antitrust regulators consider before challenging a transaction?
  2. 2.2 What are the obligations of the acquirer and target firms according to the Williams Act?
  3. 2.3 Discuss the pros and cons of federal antitrust laws.
  4. 2.4 When is a person or firm required to submit a Schedule 13(D) to the SEC? What is the purpose of such a filing?
  5. 2.5 Give examples of the types of actions that may be required by the parties to a proposed merger subject to an FTC consent decree.
  6. 2.6 Ameritech and SBC Communications received permission from the FCC to combine to form the nation’s largest local telephone company. The FCC gave its approval, subject to conditions requiring that the companies open their markets to rivals and enter new markets to compete with established local phone companies, in an effort to reduce the cost of local phone calls and give smaller communities access to appropriate phone service. SBC had considerable difficulty in complying with its agreement with the FCC. Over an 18-month period, SBC paid the US government $38.5 million for failing to provide rivals with adequate access to its network. The government noted that SBC failed to make available its network in a timely manner, meet installation deadlines, and notify competitors when their orders were filled. Comment on the fairness and effectiveness of using the imposition of heavy fines to promote government-imposed outcomes rather than free market-determined outcomes.
  7. 2.7 In an effort to gain approval of their proposed merger from the FTC, top executives from Exxon Corporation and Mobil Corporation argued that they needed to merge because of the increasingly competitive world oil market. Falling oil prices during much of the late 1990s put a squeeze on oil industry profits. Moreover, giant state-owned oil companies pose a competitive threat because of their access to huge amounts of capital. To offset these factors, Exxon and Mobil argued that they had to combine to achieve substantial cost savings. Why were the Exxon and Mobil executives emphasizing efficiencies as a justification for this merger?
  8. 2.8 How important is properly defining the market segment in which the acquirer and target companies compete in determining the potential increase in market power if the two firms are permitted to combine? Explain your answer.
  9. 2.9 Comment on whether antitrust policy can be used as an effective means of encouraging innovation. Explain your answer.
  10. 2.10 The Sarbanes-Oxley Act has been very controversial. Discuss the arguments for and against the Act. Which side do you find more convincing, and why?

Answers to these Chapter Discussion Questions are available in the Online Instructor’s Guide for instructors using this book (https://www.elsevier.com/books-and-journals/book-companion/9780128150757).

End of Chapter Case Study: Anti-Competitive Concerns Shrink Size of Drugstore Megamerger

Key Points: To Illustrate

  •  When antitrust regulation is applied,
  •  How anticompetitive regulatory issues are often resolved, and
  •  Unintended consequences of regulatory delays.

The year 2017 was a difficult year for healthcare transactions seeking regulatory approval. A federal judge blocked a planned $37 billion merger between health insurance giants Aetna and Humana in January after the Justice Department concluded that the deal should not proceed due to antitrust concerns. The following month another federal judge blocked a pending $48 billion merger between Anthem and Cigna for similar reasons. Likewise, a proposed merger between drugstore chains Walgreens Boots Alliance (Walgreens) and Rite Aid Corporation (Rite Aid) had to be revised three times in order to get regulatory approval. The deal was finally approved almost 2 years after it was first announced.

While sales and profits at Walgreens have been rising, Rite Aid has seen its sales decline and losses grow in recent years. The heavily debt-burdened chain had allowed its retail outlets to deteriorate making it more difficult to attract customers. The firm appeared to be showing signs of a potential “death spiral” in which customer attrition would erode cash flow further limiting the firm’s ability to upgrade its stores. The ongoing loss of customers if sustained could eventually make the firm unable to service its debt.

Reminiscent of a Hollywood movie advertised as years in the making, Walgreens announced that it would acquire its competitor Rite Aid on October 27, 2015 for $9 per share in a deal valued at $9.4 billion. The completion of the deal was contingent on gaining shareholder and regulatory approval. The deal involved two of the largest pharmacy chains in the US. In an effort to garner regulatory approval, Walgreens said it would be willing to divest up to 1000 stores. Together the two chains operate 12,900 stores in the US. Walgreens operates 13,100 stores in 13 countries.

Walgreens's CEO stated publicly that cost savings alone could total more than $1 billion annually. On December 21, 2016, regional pharmacy Fred’s agreed to acquire 865 Rite Aid stores as a result of the merger for $950 million. Due to the planned sale of stores to Fred’s, Walgreens would be acquiring significantly fewer stores than envisioned in the original deal. To address this issue, Walgreens negotiated a second deal to lower the price of the acquisition from $9.4 billion to $7.4 billion on January 17, 2017 and delayed closing by 6 months.

On June 29, 2017, Walgreen’s announced that it would drop its original plan to acquire Rite Aid because of ongoing regulatory resistance. Instead, Walgreens agreed in a third transformation of the original deal to buy about half of Rite Aid’s existing stores for $5.18 billion in cash. Walgreens would acquire 2186 stores, 3 distribution centers, and a portion of Rite Aid’s inventory. This deal was later revised in the face of continued resistance from the Federal Trade Commission (FTC). On September 19, 2017, the FTC finally approved a fourth deal to purchase 1932 Rite Aid stores for $4.38 billion. Even with the reduction in the number of stores acquired, Walgreens is now larger than CVS Health Corp. The planned sale of Rite Aid outlets to Fred’s was terminated.

Rite Aid is the largest drugstore chain on the East Coast and the third largest in the US. Its major competitors are CVS and Walgreens. Prior to the purchase of stores from Rite Aid, Walgreens was the second largest pharmacy store chain in the US behind CVS. From the announcement of the initial deal in which Walgreens was to buy all of Rite Aid, the FTC had raised concerns that the transaction would reduce competition and lead to rising prices. In many parts of the East Coast Rite Aid was the major alternative for consumers to Walgreens. The absorption of Rite Aid so it was thought would drive up prices as consumers had no alternative but to frequent Walgreens's pharmacies. Additional concerns at the FTC emerged as the deal morphed from a merger into a buyout of specific stores that Rite Aid would be so emasculated as a result of selling off so many of its retail outlets that it would not be a viable competitor to Walgreens.

Walgreens had to completely change the structure of the deal to get regulatory approval when it became clear regulators would not approve an acquisition of the entire firm. Under antitrust law, a deal can proceed without a vote by the commissioners of the FTC if the FTC declines to extend the review period by issuing a second request for information from the companies. The second request initiates an in-depth investigation further prolonging the review process. Walgreens wanted to avoid a second request for information from the FTC.

The lengthy regulatory review process has eroded Rite Aid shareholder value. Each time Walgreens revised the offer in an attempt to get FTC approval, the firm also renegotiated the purchase price down. Rite Aid was at the mercy of Walgreens which in turn was at the mercy of the FTC. From the initial offer in late 2015 through closing Rite Aid shares lost half of their value. During this period, the attractiveness of many Rite Aid stores continued to deteriorate as Rite Aid had little incentive to refurbish stores that it might not own once the deal was completed.

After the sale of so many stores, Rite Aid’s future looks bleak. The firm intends to use the proceeds of the sale of its storefronts to reduce its indebtedness. But the firm’s constricted cash flow limits its ability to upgrade its pharmacies and to attract new customers. The firm faces the prospect of continued loss of market share.

Ironically, the new deal achieves many of the same strategic goals Walgreens sought through a merger with Rite Aid. Walgreens still gains additional scale and volume to get larger discounts on bulk purchases and gained as much as 70% of the geographic coverage it would have achieved with the merger. In the new deal, Walgreens is paying more per store. Walgreens is paying $2.4 million per Rite Aid store, higher than under previous agreements where it would have paid $2.04 to $2.06 million per store. However, Walgreens is getting a better deal on stores it is buying from Rite Aid Corp than it would have under the merger plan, because it was able to “cherry pick” many of the most profitable locations. Therefore, the higher price per store would seem justified.

Under the merger plan it would have had to take all the stores and to assume Rite Aid’s outstanding long-term debt and other liabilities. Under the final agreement, Walgreens did not assume any Rite Aid debt. The deal also resulted in less borrowing by Walgreens to finance the purchase price. The net result of the Walgreen transaction is that it has effectively removed a competitor for less than it would have cost under the original proposal.

The major unknown is how much Walgreens will have to spend to upgrade the stores that it purchased. Rite Aid, as part of the agreement, has an option to purchase its generic drugs through an affiliate of Walgreens at cost for 10 years. This was another concession Walgreens made to the FTC to get approval. The expectation is that the prices Rite Aid pays will be close to what Walgreens pays for generics. In the final analysis, it is possible that the FTC in an effort to protect consumers from a better capitalized Walgreens may have created a far weaker competitor in Rite Aid incapable of challenging the new industry leader.

Discussion Questions

  1. 1. What is antitrust policy and why is it important? What does the often used phrase “antitrust concerns” mean?
  2. 2. In analyzing whether the purchase of Rite Aid stores would result in anticompetitive practices, the FTC examined Walgreens’ regional market share before and after the sale of Rite Aid’s stores. What factors other than market share should be considered in determining whether a potential transaction might result in anticompetitive practices?
  3. 3. What are the risks to Walgreens and Rite Aid of delaying the closing date? Be specific.
  4. 4. Who do you think are the winners and the losers in this deal? Consider all constituents including shareholders, consumers, suppliers, lenders, and regulators.

Solutions to these case study questions are found in the Online Instructor’s Manual available to instructors using this book (https://textbooks.elsevier.com/web/product_details.aspx?isbn=9780128150757).

References

Agrawal A., Nasser T. Insider trading in takeover targets. J. Corp. Finan. 2012;18:598–625.

Ahern K., Sosyura D. Who writes the news? Corporate press releases during merger negotiations. J. Financ. 2014;69:241–291.

Aktas N., Xu G., Yurtoglu B. She is mine: determinants and value effects of early announcements in takeovers. J. Corp. Finan. 2018;50:180–202.

Bailey W., Li H., Mao C., Zhong R. Regulation fair disclosure and earnings information: market, analyst, and corporate responses. J. Financ. 2003;58:2487–2514.

Barnett T. Message From the AAG. U.S. Department of Justice; 2008 Antitrust Division Update, Spring.

Biancini S., Ettinger D. Vertical integration and downstream collusion. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2017;53:99–113.

Breinlich H., Nocke V., Schutz N. International aspects of merger policy. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2017;50:415–429.

Brigida M., Madura J. Sources of target stock price run-up prior to acquisitions. J. Econ. Bus. 2012;64:185–198.

Brito D., Osorio A., Ribeiro R., Vasconcelos H. Unilateral effects screens for partial horizontal acquisitions: the generalized HHI and GUPPI. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2018;59:127–189.

Carletti E., Hartmann P., Ongena S. The economic impact of merger control legislation. Int. Rev. Law Econ. 2015;42:88–104.

Chen P., Xu H., Zou X. The effects and incentive of vertical mergers: an analysis from the view of operating managers. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2017;263:158–172.

Chen T., Harford J., Lin C. Do analysts matter for governance? Evidence from natural experiments. J. Financ. Econ. 2014a;115:383–410.

Cheng S., Duru A., Zhao Y. Antitakeover legislation and accounting conservatism: new evidence. J. Account. Public Policy. 2017;36:119–140.

Clinton S., Spina Pinella A., Skaife H. The implications of ineffective internal control and SOX 404 reporting for financial analysts. J. Account. Public Policy. 2014;33:303–327.

Croci E., Pantzalis C., Park J., Petmezas D. The role of corporate political strategies in M&As. J. Corp. Finan. 2017;43:260–287.

Curi C., Murgia M. Divestitures and the financial conglomerate excess value. J. Financ. Stab. 2018;36:187–207.

Dambra M., Casares Field L., Gustafson M. The JOBS Act and IPO volume: evidence that disclosure costs affect IPO decisions. J. Financ. Econ. 2015;116:121–143.

Dai R., Massoud N., Nandy D., Saunders A. Hedge funds in M&A deals: is there exploitation of insider information?. J. Corp. Finan. 2017a;47:23–45.

Denicolo V., Polo M. Duplicative research, mergers and innovation. Econ. Lett. 2018;166:56–59.

Deshpende S., Svetina M., Zhu P. Impact of European Commission merger regulation on U.S. domestic M&As. J. Multinatl. Financ. Manag. 2016;36:1–15.

Dutordoir M., Roosenboom P., Vasconcellos M. Synergy disclosures in mergers and acquisitions. Int. Rev. Financ. Anal. 2014;31:88–100.

Federal Trade Commission. A Study of the Commission’s Divestiture Process. Bureau of Competition; 1999b.

Fidrmuc J., Roosenboom P., Zhang E. Antitrust merger review costs and acquirer lobbying. J. Corp. Finan. 2018;51:72–97.

Francis T., Knutson R. Wave of megadeals tests antitrust limits in U.S. Wall Street J. 2015 October 19.

Gao N., Peng N., Strong N. What determines horizontal merger antitrust case selection?. J. Corp. Finan. 2017;46:51–76.

Gu Y., Zhang L. The impact of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act on corporate innovation. J. Econ. Bus. 2017;90:17–30.

Gunter A., van Dijk M. The impact of European antitrust policy: evidence from the stock market. Int. Rev. Law Econ. 2016;46:20–33.

Heflin F., Subramanyam K., Zhang Y. Regulation FD and the financial information environment: early evidence. Account. Rev. 2003;78:1–37.

Ismail A. Does management’s forecast of merger synergies explain the premium paid, method of payment, and management motives?. Financ. Manag. (Winter):2011;879–910.

Kallunki J., Kallunki J.P., Nilsson H., Puhakka M. Do an insider's wealth and income matter in the decision to engage in insider trading?. J. Financ. Econ. 2018;130:135–165.

Karolyi G., Taboada A. Regulatory arbitrage and cross border acquisitions. J. Financ. 2015;70:2395–2450.

Kedia S., Zhou X. Informed trading around acquisitions: evidence from corporate bonds. J. Financ. Mark. 2014;16:61–103.

Lee I., Lemmon M., Yan L., Sequeira J. Do voluntary restrictions on insider trading eliminate informed insider trading?. J. Corp. Finan. 2015;29:158–178.

Offenberg D., Officer M. The totality of change-in-control payments. J. Corp. Finan. 2014;29:75–87.

Saljanin S. Signaling through public antitrust enforcement. Econ. Lett. 2017;159:4–6.

Shapiro C. Antitrust in a time of populism. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2018 (Forthcoming).

Sherman A. Mergers and Acquisitions From A to Z: Strategic and Practical Guidance for Small- and Middle-Market Buyers and Sellers. second ed. AMACOM: New York; 2006.

Truitt W. The Corporation. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press; 2006.

Velikonja U. Reporting agency performance: behind the SEC’s enforcement statistics. Cornell Law Rev. 2016;101.

Wang Y., Lahr H. Takeover law to protect shareholders: increasing efficiency or merely redistributing gains?. J. Corp. Finan. 2017;43:288–315.


1 Note that a private company can be subject to the same reporting requirements if it merges with a public shell company in a reverse merger in which the private company becomes a publicly traded entity.

2 Acquisitions and divestitures are usually deemed significant if the equity interest in the acquired assets or the amount paid or received exceeds 10% of the total book value of the assets of the registrant and its subsidiaries.

3 In some instances, bidders announce that they are in negotiation well before reaching agreement with the target firm to enlist the support of target shareholders by signally how attractive the combination of the two firms could be (Aktas et al., 2018).

4 According to the Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1984, those convicted of engaging in insider trading are required to give back their illegal profits and to pay a penalty three times the amount of such profits. A 1988 US Supreme Court ruling gives investors the right to claim damages from a firm that falsely denied it was involved in negotiations that subsequently resulted in a merger.

5 If insiders normally buy 100 shares and sell 50 shares each month, the normal increase in their holdings would be 50. However, if their purchases drop to 90 and sales to 30 each month, their holdings rise by 60 shares.

6 Agrawal and Nasser (2012).

7 Lee et al. (2015).

8 Dai et al. (2017a).

9 Kedia and Zhou (2014).

10 Kallunki et al. (2018).

11 As a small but growing source of financing for business start-ups, equity crowdfunding refers to the online offering of private company securities to investors.

12 Dambra et al. (2015).

13 Velikonja (2016).

14 The Williams Act is vague as to what is a tender offer so as not to construe any purchase by one firm of another’s shares in the open market as a tender offer. The courts have ruled that a tender offer is characterized by either of the following conditions: (i) a bidder announcing publicly the intent to purchase a substantial block of another firm’s stock to gain control or (ii) the actual purchase of a substantial portion of another firm’s shares in the open market or through a privately negotiated block purchase of the firm’s shares.

15 Acquirers often initiate two-tiered tender offers, in which target shareholders receive a higher price if they tender their shares in the first tier than those submitting shares in the second tier. The “best price” rule simply means that all shareholders tendering their shares in the first tier must be paid the price offered for those shares in the first tier, and those tendering shares in the second tier are paid the price offered for second-tier shares unless precluded by state law.

16 Offenberg and Officer (2014).

17 An unintended consequence of the law’s requirement that firms make public material weaknesses in internal controls is the reduced coverage of such firms by financial analysts in the year following such announcements (Clinton et al., 2014). Less coverage could result in reduced awareness among investors of potential problems with the firm’s earnings quality. This could be mitigated somewhat as investor interest in such firms also is likely to decline in line with waning analyst coverage. Chen et al. (2014a) find that firms receiving less analyst coverage can contribute to a firm’s CEO receiving “excessive” compensation, managers making value-destroying acquisitions, and managers engaging more aggressively in managing reported earnings.

18 Gu and Zhang (2017) argue that improved monitoring by the board resulting from the addition of outside managers encourages more innovation. Innovative projects are inherently risky and are less likely to be undertaken by entrenched and bureaucratic board members and senior managers with a vested interest in avoiding risk.

19 Brigida and Madura (2012).

20 Ostensibly undermining his statement that funding was in place, 2 weeks later Elon Musk stated that Tesla would remain public as “investors had convinced him that the firm should not go private.”

21 All studies show an increase in voluntary disclosure by firms (Heflin et al., 2003; Bailey et al., 2003; Dutordoir et al., 2014). However, Bailey et al. (2003) reports an increase in the variation of analysts’ forecasts but no change in the volatility of share prices following the introduction of Regulation FD. In contrast, Heflin et al. (2003) finds no change in the variation of analysts’ forecast but a decrease in share price volatility.

22 Dutordoir et al. (2014).

23 Ismail (2011).

24 Ahern and Sosyura (2014).

25 Guo et al. (2018b).

26 Truitt (2006).

27 Saljanin (2017).

28 Fidrmuc et al. (2018).

29 The ultimate parent entity is the firm at the top of the chain of ownership if the actual buyer is a subsidiary.

30 In 2007, there were 2201 HSR filings with the FTC (about 20% of total transactions), compared to 1768 in 2006 (Barnett, 2008). Of these, about 4% typically are challenged and about 2% require second requests for information. About 97% of the 37,701 M&A deals filed with the FTC between 1991 and 2004 were approved without further scrutiny.

31 Regulators filed a suit on February 27, 2004, to block Oracle’s $26 per-share hostile bid for PeopleSoft on antitrust grounds. On September 9, 2004, a US District Court judge denied a request by US antitrust authorities that he issue an injunction against the deal, arguing that the government failed to prove that large businesses can turn to only three suppliers (i.e., Oracle, PeopleSoft, and SAP) for business applications software.

32 In a report evaluating the results of 35 divestiture orders entered between 1990 and 1994, the FTC concluded that the use of consent decrees to limit market power resulting from a business combination has proven to be successful by creating viable competitors (Federal Trade Commission, 1999b).

33 Critics of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index argue that it measures only the degree of industry concentration without estimating the impact of a merger on potential productivity improvement. For an alternative to the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index. For a discussion of how to modify the HHI index to account for partial takeovers, see Brito et al. (2018).

34 Francis and Knutson (2015).

35 Horizontal mergers can stimulate innovation by eliminating R&D overlap and by better aligning projects with the combined firms’ goals (Denicolo and Polo, 2018).

36 Shapiro (2018).

37 A supply chain is the network linking a firm to its suppliers in order to produce and distribute a product.

38 Chen et al. (2017).

39 Biancini and Ettinger (2017).

40 Traditional telecom and media companies are racing to better compete with the likes of Google, Facebook, Netflix and Amazon.com, which have disrupted the traditional TV market. Having spent $49 billion 2 years ago to buy DirecTV, AT&T is determined to own content, because it anticipates that viewers will increasingly watch media content on mobile phones and tablets.

41 The “rule of reason” is a legal doctrine developed to apply the Sherman Antitrust Act. It states that an attempt should be made to weigh the aspects of a potentially restrictive business practices that support competition against its anticompetitive effects in order to determine whether the practice should be prohibited. For example, price fixing is illegal per se but monopoly is not. The combination of two firms resulting in dominant market share may be acceptable if it can be shown that the combination will result in improved operating efficiency.

42 Gao et al. (2017).

43 A natural monopoly is one that results from high fixed costs or start-up costs of operating a business in a specific industry. Such industries are characterized by very high entry barriers such as utilities.

44 While predatory pricing (selling below cost) is illegal, it is extremely difficult to win predatory pricing lawsuits as the court needs to prove that the alleged predator can in fact raise prices and recover its losses.

45 Gunter and van Dijk (2016).

46 Carletti et al. (2015).

47 Croci et al. (2017).

48 Curi and Murgia (2018).

49 On October 31, 2018, the US Federal Reserve, the nation’s largest regulator of financial institutions, recommended extending this relief to banks with total assets exceeding $700 billion. Not expected to take effect until 2019, the new proposal would lower regulatory requirements under Dodd-Frank to about 70%–80% of existing standards. It is unclear at this time how the Fed will regulate the US-based subsidiaries of large foreign banks.

50 Examples include the Fair Credit Reporting Act of 1970, the Fair Debt Collections Act of 1977, the Video Privacy Protection Act of 1988, the Cable TV Protection and Competition Act of 1992, and the 1996 Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act.

51 For a good discussion of this debate, see Wang and Lahr (2017).

52 By precluding such actions, these provisions limit LBOs from using asset sales to reduce indebtedness.

53 Cheng et al. (2017).

54 Truitt (2006).

55 The “commerce clause” refers to Article 1, Section 8, Clause 3 of the US Constitution, which gives Congress the power “to regulate commerce … among the …states, ….”

56 Sherman (2006).

57 Breinlich et al. (2017).

58 Deshpende et al. (2016).

59 Karolyi and Taboada (2015).

"To view the full reference list for the book, click here"

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset