Chapter 3

The Corporate Takeover Market: Common Takeover Tactics, Antitakeover Defenses, and Corporate Governance

Abstract

Corporate governance refers to the rules and processes by which a business is controlled, regulated, or operated. This chapter explains the factors that impact governance both internal and external to the firm, with a particular focus on the role of corporate takeovers in disciplining failing corporate managers. Significant attention is paid to the pivotal role of the board of directors in promoting good corporate governance and in overseeing the M&A process. Common takeover strategies ranging from friendly to hostile buyouts and tactics including bear hugs, proxy contests, and tender offers are discussed in detail. The chapter also addresses how bidding strategies are developed and how common pitfalls are resolved. Activist investment strategies as an alternative to takeovers also are analyzed. Finally, this chapter addresses the advantages and disadvantages of alternative defenses employed in change of control battles.

Keywords

Takeover tactics; Takeover defenses; Corporate governance; Poison pills; Staggered boards; Classified boards; Corporate activists; Mergers; Acquisitions; Corporate restructuring; Consent solicitation; For cause provisions; Greenmail; Fair price provisions; Restructuring; Share buyback; Share repurchase; White knights; Litigation; Proxy contests; Bear hug; Hostile takeovers; Friendly takeovers; Tender offer; Bidding strategies; Consent solicitation; Supermajority provisions; Dual class recapitalization; Recapitalization; Shark repellents; Public offerings; Board of directors; Activism; Activist investors; Shareholder value; Firm value; Board diversity

Treat a person as he is, and he will remain as he is. Treat him as he could be, and he will become what he should be.

Jimmy Johnson

Inside Mergers and Acquisitions: Auction Euphoria Can Result in Buyer’s Remorse

Key points

  •  Buyers usually prefer friendly acquisitions but when the target firm is sufficiently attractive they sometimes turn hostile.
  •  Such circumstances can attract multiple bidders.
  •  Disciplined bidders will walk away when the target’s demands appear excessive.
  •  The winning bidder by paying too much finds it difficult to recover the purchase price premium and earn financial returns required by their shareholders.

At the outset, French multinational pharmaceutical company Sanofi appeared to hold all the cards in its attempted takeover of Medivation, an American biopharmaceutical firm known for developing therapies for difficult to treat illnesses. Why? Even though the nomination deadline for its annual meeting had past, Medivation allowed shareholders to act by written consent (also called consent solicitation) at any time. Under Delaware state law, where Medivation is incorporated, directors on a board in which every director is up for election at the same time can be removed at any time with or without cause.

Besides, Medivation wasn’t in the strongest position to play hardball. Not only did it have to convince bidders that they should boost their offer price but also its shareholders that it was worth retaining their investments until a buyer could be found to pay “top dollar.” This was a particularly risky proposition since Medivation did not have sufficient data in the testing process to ensure that it would receive government approval to market their most recent blockbuster cancer fighting drug. Moreover, sales of the firm’s prostate cancer drug Xtandi appeared to be moderating.

Sanofi had already upped its initial bid of $52.50 per share to $58.50 plus a $3 contingent value right, a pay-out based on the drug’s future performance. The higher bid represented an almost 50% premium to the average Medivation share price trading range during the 2 months prior to media speculation that the firm was a takeover target. Each of its offers was rebuffed by Medivation’s board as undervaluing the company.

On May 10, 2016 attempting to ignite a bidding war, Medivation approached potential buyers and agreed to open its books to Pfizer, among other potential bidders. In response, Sanofi attempted to go hostile with its bid and prepared a list of nominees to replace Medivation’s board through a proxy battle. Medivation urged its shareholders to reject Sanofi’s attempt to replace the board stating its current business strategy promised greater long-term value than Sanofi’s offer. With so many suitors, things did not look good for Sanofi, a company not known for moving quickly.

On July 5, 2016, Medivation announced it had signed a confidentiality agreement with a number of parties who had expressed interest in a possible deal in a purchase price range attractive to its board. By early August, the sales process entered into its final stages with Pfizer making a legally binding offer. Pfizer announced on August 22, 2016 that it had reached an agreement to acquire Medivation in all cash bid of $81.50 per share, which represented a 33% premium over Sanofi’s highest offer price.

The risk to Pfizer is that it is overpaying. While Medivation is a good fit, the auction process may have made it impractical for the firm to recover the premium paid and to earn the financial returns demanded by investors. With Medivation’s cancer drug sales moderating, Pfizer may have to rely on Medivation’s new drugs for breast cancer to fuel future profits. The justification for Pfizer’s lofty purchase price for Medivation may rest on optimistic growth assumptions. If they are not realized, the firm’s management and board may regret deeply their decision.

Chapter Overview

The corporate takeover market in which control is transferred from the seller to the buyer serves two important functions in a free market economy: the allocation of resources and as a mechanism for disciplining failing corporate managers. Ideally, corporate resources are transferred to those who can manage them more efficiently. Replacing inept managers helps to promote good corporate governance and in turn a firm’s financial performance.

Corporate governance refers to the rules and processes by which a business is controlled, regulated, or operated. Traditionally, the goal has been to protect shareholder rights. More recently, this has expanded to encompass additional corporate stakeholders. For our purposes, corporate governance is about leadership and accountability, and it involves all those factors internal and external to the firm that interact to protect the rights of corporate stakeholders. That is, the long-held goal of the firm of maximizing shareholder value necessarily encompasses balancing the interests of all key stakeholder groups. Failure to do so can derail efforts to maximize shareholder value as disputes arise among stakeholder groups over control and how cash flow will be utilized.

Disputes among constituent groups generally fall into two categories: vertical and horizontal. Vertical disputes result from disagreements between managers and shareholders, while horizontal disputes are those between other stakeholder groups. Vertical disputes arise when managers, as agents of shareholders, make decisions to increase their wealth and power, which may not be in the best interests of shareholders. Horizontal disputes arise when non-managerial stakeholders have conflicting goals such as different classes of shareholders, creditors versus equity holders, short-term versus long-term investors, and so on. Vertical conflicts tend to be more common in mature widely-held publicly traded firms where individual shareholders generally exert less influence. Horizontal conflicts are more common in younger, privately held firms in which control tends to be concentrated among a few shareholder groups and equity structures can consist of various classes of common and preference stock. Horizontal conflicts will be discussed in more detail in Chapter 10.

Fig. 3.1 illustrates the range of factors affecting corporate governance, including the corporate takeover market. A chapter review (including practice questions) is available in the file folder entitled Student Study Guide contained on the companion site to this book (https://www.elsevier.com/books-and-journals/book-companion/9780128150757).

Fig. 3.1
Fig. 3.1 Factors affecting corporate governance.

Corporate Governance

When capital markets are liquid, investors discipline bad managers by selling their shares (i.e., the market model). When capital markets are illiquid, bad managers are disciplined by those owning large blocks of stock in the firm (i.e., the control model). Table 3.1 summarizes the characteristics of these two common models of corporate governance. The following sections describe in detail those factors internal and external to the firm, including M&As, impacting corporate governance. The underlying theme in these sections is that effective firm-level shareholder protections combined with liquid capital markets, strong legal protections, and rigorous enforcement of such protections work together to lower a firm’s cost of raising equity capital.1

Table 3.1

Alternative Models of Corporate Governance
Market model applicable when:Control model applicable when:
Capital markets are highly liquidCapital markets are illiquid
Equity ownership is widely dispersedEquity ownership is heavily concentrated
Board members are largely independentBoard members are largely “insiders”
Ownership and control are separateOwnership and control overlap
Financial disclosure is highFinancial disclosure is limited
Shareholders focus more on short-term gainsShareholders focus more on long-term gains

Factors Internal to the Firm

Corporate governance is affected by the effectiveness of the firm’s board, internal controls and incentive systems, takeover defenses, culture, and bond covenants.

The Board of Directors/Management

Corporate board structures differ among countries and have evolved into two basic types: unitary (single) and two-tier (dual) structures. A unitary board is composed of both company managers and independent directors, which make decisions as a group. An independent (or outside) director is someone who has not worked for the firm in the past, is not a current manager, does not stand to benefit financially beyond what is paid to other board directors, and is not a captive of the firm’s current culture or way of doing business. A two-tier board consists of a management board composed only of company executives, including the chief executive officer, whose responsibilities are to run the firm’s operations, and a separate supervisory board comprised only of independent directors. Overseeing the management board, the supervisory board is responsible for strategic decisions and often contains other stakeholders such as employees and environmental groups.

The United States and the United Kingdom are examples of countries having mandated unitary board structures, while Germany and Austria use the two-tiered board structure. In other countries such as France, firms are permitted to switch between the two types of structures. Which structure a firm chooses seems to reflect the extent to which shareholders see potential significant conflicts with management as to how the firm should be managed.

Finance literature commonly presumes a board’s ultimate responsibility is to maximize shareholder wealth. In practice, the way boards view their responsibilities varies widely ranging from German and Austrian firms’ supervisory boards attempting to balance the interests of all stakeholder groups to US firms which view maximizing shareholder wealth as their primary responsibility.2

What follows is more descriptive of a unitary board structure. For such boards, the primary responsibilities are to advise the CEO and to monitor firm performance. The board hires, fires, and sets CEO pay and is expected to oversee management, corporate strategy, and the firm’s financial reports to shareholders. Some board members may be employees or founding family members (so-called inside directors); others may be affiliated with the firm through a banking relationship, a law firm retained by the firm, or someone who represents a customer or supplier. The value of such directors often lies in their substantial organizational knowledge. However, they may be subject to conflicts of interest causing them to act in ways not in the shareholders’ best interests. For example, boards with directors working for banks that have made loans to the firm may favor diversifying acquisitions that are financed with stock rather than cash.3 Such acquisitions may smooth out fluctuations in consolidated cash flow and using stock rather than cash to pay for them preserves the firm’s ability to meet interest and principal payments on its existing debt. However, the use of the stock may dilute the acquiring shareholders ownership interest in the combined firms.

The Role of Independent Directors

Potential conflicts of interest have led some observers to argue that boards should be composed primarily of independent directors. The presumption is that independent directors improve firm performance due to their objectivity and experience outside the industry. However, their lack of extensive firm specific knowledge may limit their ability to make informed decisions on a timely basis. However, their presence can reduce monitoring costs as they may be better able to limit the self-serving actions of insiders.4 Boards with more independent directors are less likely to go bankrupt. And boards interested in making acquisitions are better served to select independent directors with past experience in making successful acquisitions.5 Finally, the combination of outside director skills, knowledge, and experience (i.e., human capital) and their network of contacts (i.e., social capital) provide senior management with valuable counsel in making strategic decisions. The human and social capital of outside directors often is critical to successful cross-border acquisitions given their legal, social, and cultural complexity.6 Independent directors with significant knowledge of a firm’s business may combine the best of both outside and inside directors. Outside directors with experience in the industry in which the firm competes tend to have the greatest impact on firm value in companies with large investment programs (particularly R&D) and excess cash balances. This is consistent with the notion that investment decisions made by industry experts are more likely to boost the value of the firm. Their experience also appears to be very helpful in navigating firms during crises. In contrast, prior industry experience is less helpful in dynamically changing industries in which the future is likely to look far different from the past.7

CEO Duality

Studies show that firm performance can be improved by more independent boards and by eliminating so-called CEO duality, the situation in which the CEO is also the chairman of the board.8 With one person serving both roles, so the argument goes, decision making can be faster because the firm’s senior management is unified. However, it also is possible for the CEO to assert control over the board making it more difficult for the board to perform its monitoring function and to discipline management when necessary. Thus, when CEOs also serve as Chairman, there may be too great a concentration of power. Perhaps underscoring this point, CEOs that serve as Chairman on average earn 20% more than those reporting to a Board Chairman who is an independent director.9

There is evidence that a greater concentration of power in the CEO can contribute to lower acquisition premiums.10 Such CEOs often have extensive industry networks giving access to better information, significant takeover experience allowing them to better assess risk, and are more skilled negotiators.

Behavioral and Demographic Characteristics of CEOs and Board Members

The quality of CEO and board decisions also is affected by the degree of risk aversion and the age of the CEO. However, the effects of the gender makeup of the board are less clear. Each of these factors is discussed next.

CEO acquisition decisions tend to mirror their personal stock portfolio trading patterns. Such trading patterns may reflect the willingness of CEOs to accept risk. Those CEOs who show little portfolio turnover in their own stock investments (i.e., engage in relatively more conservative trading practices) tend to be more successful at avoiding M&As that destroy their firm’s shareholder value than do CEOs whose personal portfolios exhibit high turnover.11 Another way to measure a CEO’s willingness to accept risk is by examining their political affiliation. Those whose political contributions suggest they are republican tend to be less willing to make risky investments. Republican CEOs (often viewed as more conservatively leaning than democrat CEOs) are less likely to undertake M&As. When they do, they are more likely to select targets in the same industry and those for which financial and operating data is readily available. They also avoid the use of earnouts and tend to use cash to acquire target stock or assets. While there no short-term difference in firm performance, republican/conservative leaning CEOs tend to create greater long-term firm value.

Younger CEOs tend to be more acquisitive than older ones. CEO compensation often reflects firm size, with CEOs of smaller firms earning less than those in larger companies. This creates an incentive for CEOs to pursue acquisitions earlier in their careers recognizing the potential for future large, permanent increases in compensation. This incentive is strongest among firms where CEOs likely anticipate that they can influence high post-acquisition compensation.12

Despite a large body of research on the gender composition of boards, the literature does not provide clear and consistent answers as to what effects can be expected from a more gender balanced board.13 Some studies show that gender differences can impact director behavior, decisions, and firm outcomes. For example, boards with more women directors tend to be less acquisitive and to pay lower premiums when takeovers occur, perhaps reflecting less hubris and tolerance for risk than their male counterparts.14 But historical stereotypes may be poor predictors of future outcomes. In the US, business start-ups founded by women are at record levels reflecting a level of confidence and willingness to take chances that may not have been evident in recent decades.

Trends in Board Composition and CEO Duality

While it continues to be common for one person to hold dual roles as CEO and Chairman, the number of independent directors on boards has been increasing over the years. In the early 1990s, about 40% of boards were composed of senior corporate managers or individuals affiliated with the corporation. In recent years, more than 90% of boards have only one or two non-independent directors. Despite this trend, more independent boards are not a panacea. There is little evidence that underperforming managers are more likely to be removed today than in the past. Moreover, having more independent directors does not seem to lead to lower CEO pay.15 Furthermore, less independent boards are associated with higher announcement date financial returns when non-independent board members possess significant information about the target firm.16 In such instances, the advisory role of the board is more important than its performance monitoring function.

With more than one-fifth of the board directors in Fortune 500 companies in 2013 on more than one board, the demands on directors’ time can be substantial. The most talented independent directors, often on multiple boards, are most likely to spend the bulk of their time on those boards of firms held in the highest esteem by their peers and investors. This suggests that they may be less effective on other boards on which they serve, because they have an incentive to devote most of their time on boards that add to their reputations.17 Furthermore, firms whose directors reduce the number of boards on which they serve are associated with higher profitability, market to book ratios, and a tendency of board member willingness to serve on committees.18

Despite the potential improvement in governance resulting from separating the Chairman and CEO positions, shareholders have proven largely comfortable with the combined role of these two positions. According to the proxy advisory firm Institutional Shareholder Services, only 6% of the 372 proposals to separate the roles at S&P 500 companies during the decade ending in 2015 were approved by shareholders. Perhaps the tepid interest shareholders have in eliminating CEO duality reflects the tendency of firm performance to be higher in firms having CEO duality and a reputation for protecting shareholder rights; in firms with weak governance, CEO duality can harm firm performance. Therefore, simply separating the two functions without having a board that is actively protecting shareholder interests is unlikely to increase shareholder value.

Board Performance, Selection, and Compensation

The oft used adage that information is power is certainly true in the board room. Well connected CEOs often have access to information not readily available to others giving them greater control over board agendas and the ability to achieve consensus among board members. Access to better information also makes it more difficult to remove underperforming CEOs who claim they have a more accurate view of future competitive trends and that continued reliance of their business strategy will result in eventual success.19

Political connections matter. Acquirers whose board members or senior managers include former politicians and regulators are more likely to receive regulatory approval, realize higher announcement date returns, and exhibit superior postmerger operating performance than those that do not.20 Investors think such acquirers may receive more favorable treatment by regulators and be able to acquire more synergistic targets such as direct competitors. Former politicians and regulators can be helpful in navigating the regulatory process, gaining access to decision makers for purposes of lobbying, and in receiving government contracts.

According to a 2017 survey by the National Association of Corporate Directors, boards of companies with market capitalizations of at least $10 billion average about 10.9 members, about one-half of their average size during the 1970s. Smaller boards tend to be more effective, since each member can wield more influence as their vote represents a larger percentage of the total board, thereby effectively reducing the power of the CEO. Smaller boards also are more likely to replace a CEO due to poor performance. Consistent with the perceived effectiveness of smaller boards, General Electric announced it would reduce the size of its board from 18 to 12 (including 3 new members) following its announcement of a new restructuring plan in December 2017.

Despite progress in recent years, boards often do not discipline underperforming CEOs as quickly as perhaps they should due to a variety of factors. Boards may be slow to dismiss such managers due to cronyism, concern about how it reflects on board members, or a concern about investor reaction. For publicly traded firms, dismissing high profile CEOs attracts substantial investor attention. CEO termination reflects negatively on the board that hired the CEO, raising investor concerns about board competence. Such concerns could impact the firm’s future cost of financing21 and may help explain why CEOs often seem to be compensated for M&A deals that create as well as destroy value.22

How board members themselves are selected may be problematic. The selection of board members may be more a function of their accumulated experience and public profile as CEOs than past job performance. For example, CEOs with substantial acquisition experience are more likely to be selected for a higher number of directorships with little regard to whether their past acquisitions created or destroyed shareholder value.23 When this is the case, the existence of independent board members with significant senior level investment banking experience may be increasingly important. While acquiring firms having such directors have a higher probability of making acquisitions, they also tend to exhibit higher announcement date financial returns, pay lower takeover premiums and advisory fees, and show superior long-term performance than firms that do not.24

Board members are compensated using different types of incentive payments, including stock, stock options, and fees paid to attend meetings. Directors on boards of larger, more complex firms tend to be paid more. Firms with greater growth opportunities pay a larger percentage of director compensation in the form of equity, presumably to better align director interests with those of the firm’s shareholders.25

When a CEO’s compensation is dependent on equity, shareholders are more confident that acquisitions are likely to enhance firm value, because the CEO will share in any losses resulting from poor acquisition decisions. This is especially true in firms where shares are widely held giving senior management significant decision making power. However, equity based compensation becomes less important in the presence of large block holders, common in Western Europe, who closely monitor firm performance.26 Block holders having informational advantages and governance experience obtained from multiple block holdings tend to be more effective at monitoring board and management performance.27

In the end, too much emphasis is placed on form over substance in achieving effective governance. Form focuses on the size and distribution of the board between independent and non-independent directors and whether the Chairman and CEO positions are held by different individuals. Substantive improvement in governance often comes more from the integrity of board members and senior managers and the willingness of board members to remain engaged in the ongoing activities of the business.

Board Diversity and Firm Performance

Board diversity has many facets including skills, gender, age, ethnicity, educational background, financial expertise, and breadth of board experience. The combined effect of different sources of diversity appears to be more important in how boards achieve consensus than any single factor.

Board diversity can result in better board decisions and improved firm performance when it stimulates more diverse thinking, nimble decision making is not required, and consensus is possible. More diverse boards tend to be less leveraged and to maintain greater dividend distributions. However, these more conservative financial policies do not appear to result in underinvestment as demonstrated by such firms spending a greater share of revenue on research and development. Moreover, both the operating performance and valuation multiples tend to increase with increasing board diversity. Board diversity appears to have less impact on moderating firm risk when the majority of board members have been in place for a long time. Long-tenure board members may be less likely to disagree with strong CEOs due to their close personal relationship and may be more susceptible to “group think.”28

Another recent study makes a distinction between boards with highly diverse skills and those with a substantial concentration of skills. That is, some firms select directors with many different skills to their board, while other firms focus on a few particular skills. Those firms whose directors’ skills tend to be highly concentrated tend to outperform those whose directors have more diverse skills. Why? Firms whose boards have highly diverse skill sets may lack common ground making consensus building more challenging.29

Dealing With Activist Investors and Takeover Attempts

A common board response is to consider a settlement involving a confidentiality agreement. Sometimes settlements with activist investors are more public as the investor is offered a board seat. Such settlements may only encourage other activists who feel the board and management can be easily intimidated. Another common response is for the board to explain the firm’s business strategy more aggressively publicly arguing that the payoff from continued pursuit of its current strategy is greater than value of the activist or suitor proposal. To gain credibility among investors and other observers, the board must explain the upside potential of its strategy while clearly delineating underlying assumptions. If need be, the board often engages advisors ranging from legal counsel to investment bankers to proxy advisors, if a proxy contest is anticipated. The board must ensure that any proxy statement is supported by compelling valuations of alternative outcomes. Otherwise, investors may view the board and management as simply wanting to entrench themselves. Other types of defenses that may be employed such as poison pills are described later in this chapter.

Target Board’s Advisory Role in Takeover Bids

An important responsibility of a target firm’s board is to make recommendations to their shareholders whenever a takeover bid is made. Indeed, most takeover attempts are accompanied by a public recommendation from the target board to its shareholders. Serving in their advisory capacity, target boards often are inclined to recommend shareholders vote against takeover proposals unless the premium is widely recognized as exceeding the fair value of the firm’s shares. How target shareholders react to board recommendations reflects their perception of the board’s credibility. Ideally, the board’s recommendation would be totally objective, but in reality, their recommendations can be self-serving in that board members might lose their jobs if they support the takeover bid.

There is an interaction between the takeover premium that is offered by the bidder and the ability of the target’s board to influence shareholder decisions to accept or reject a tender offer. If the premium is very high (or very low) shareholders will have greater confidence in making their own decisions and the board’s position is largely ignored. However, if it is unclear if the premium is adequate, the influence of the board’s recommendation can be substantial. Whether the board will be ignored by target shareholders depends on its credibility as measured by the independence of its members and their industry related expertise, as well as the uncertainty among industry analysts about the true value of target shares.30 When analyst uncertainty is high, shareholders may rely more on board recommendations because the board has access to better and more complete information.

Internal Controls and Incentive Systems

These factors are critical to aligning shareholder and managerial interests. Internal controls help prevent fraud as well as encourage compliance with prevailing laws and regulations. Financial, legal and auditing functions, as well as hiring and firing policies, within the firm are examples of internal controls. Compensation, consisting of base pay, bonuses, and stock options, underpins incentive systems used to manage the firm in the manner the board deems appropriate. Management contracts formally stipulate responsibilities, term of employment, basic compensation arrangements, change in control provisions, and severance packages.

The dark side of financial incentive systems is that they may create abuses as well as positive motivations. To rectify management abuses, the Dodd-Frank Act of 2010 gives shareholders of public firms the right to vote on executive compensation. Under the new rules, such votes must occur at least once every 3 years. There is empirical evidence that this so-called “say on pay” rule helps to align executive compensation with shareholder interests.31 The Dodd-Frank Act also requires publicly traded firms to develop mechanisms for recovering compensation based on executive misconduct.

Managerial and shareholder interests can be aligned in other ways. Option exercise prices can be linked to the firm’s share price performance relative to the stock market, ensuring that increases in the stock market do not benefit managers whose companies are underperforming. Another way is for managers to own a significant portion of the firm’s outstanding stock or for the manager’s ownership of the firm’s stock to comprise a substantial share of his or her personal wealth. Aggressive incentive programs tend to improve acquirer abnormal financial returns around acquisition announcement dates for public targets and have had an even greater positive impact after the introduction of Sarbanes Oxley in 2002 which makes senior management more accountable for their actions. Senior managers at firms with high pay for performance incentive plans tend to pay 23.3% lower average merger premiums to public target firm shareholders than firms with more modest incentive plans.32

An alternative to concentrating ownership in management is for one or more shareholders who are not managers to accumulate a large block of voting shares. These block holders may be more aggressive in monitoring management and more receptive to takeovers, thereby increasing the risk to managers that they will be ousted for poor performance. Block holders can promote good governance and influence a firm’s performance by either making their concerns known to the board and management or by selling their shares. Block holders can include hedge funds, mutual funds, pension funds, individuals and other corporations.33

The link between block holders and improved firm performance is mixed. Their effectiveness in promoting good governance and in turn improved firm performance is dependent on the quality of their own governance practices. Effective block holders are those whose interests are closely aligned with other shareholders. Some block holders may exacerbate firm performance by acting to benefit themselves rather than all shareholders. Examples of so-called “private benefits” that accrue to such block holders include the payment of dividends rather than reinvestment of funds in the firm, selling products at less than prevailing market prices to firms in which the block holder is an investor, and buying products/services from suppliers in which the block holder is a shareholder.34

While management contracts can guarantee pay for failure,35 they can contribute to shareholder wealth creation by better aligning CEO interests with shareholders. They enable firms to attract and retain the best talent and encourage the pursuit of value enhancing investments, since such contracts generally align their compensation with the long-term performance of the firm and specify severance packages. Management contracts have become more popular over the years, especially for firms that are underperforming their peers or are takeover targets,36 with the percentage of S&P 500 CEOs with contracts increasing from 29% in 1990 to 50% in 2005. Acquirers, whose CEOs have employment contracts, outperform their counterparts without one in terms of financial returns by 1.3 percentage points on average when deals are announced and show greater long-term profitability. Acquirer CEOs with contracts may bargain more aggressively resulting in lower purchase price premiums paid because their total compensation depends on the long-term performance of the firm.37

Antitakeover Defenses

A firm’s board and management may employ defenses to negotiate a higher purchase price with a bidder or to solidify their current position within the firm. The range of defensive actions is detailed later in this chapter.

Corporate Culture and Values

Good governance also depends on an employee culture instilled with appropriate values and behaviors. Setting the right tone comes from the board of directors’ and senior management’s willingness to behave in a manner consistent with what they demand from other employees. A firm’s culture is often viewed by management as a valuable corporate asset; and, as such, their desire to preserve the culture can impact investment policy. For instance, firms whose cultures breed substantial trust between employees and management tend to increase cooperation and the exchange of specialized knowledge. Such firms tend to make acquisitions that are on average one-third the size of those made by other firms enabling their culture to be dominant in defining the behavior of the employees of the combined firms.38

Bond Covenants

Legally binding on both the bond issuer and the bond holder, covenants forbid the issuer from undertaking certain activities, such as dividend payments, or require the issuer to meet specific requirements, such as periodic information reporting. Strong covenants can motivate managers to pursue relatively low risk investments, such as capital expenditures, and avoid higher risk investments, such as research and development spending.

Factors External to the Firm

Federal and state legislation, the court system, regulators, institutional activists, and the corporate takeover market play key roles in maintaining good corporate governance practices.

Legislation and the Legal System

The 1933 and 1934 Securities Acts underlie US securities legislation and created the Securities and Exchange Commission, charged with writing and enforcing securities’ regulations. The US Congress has since transferred some enforcement tasks to public stock exchanges operating under SEC oversight.39 Under the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOA) of 2002, the SEC oversees the Public Company Accounting Oversight Board, whose task is to develop and enforce auditing standards. State legislation also has a significant impact on governance practices by requiring corporate charters to define the responsibilities of boards and managers with respect to shareholders.

The net effect of stronger investor protections, such as laws and regulations which increase investor access to consistent and accurate financial information, is to limit the ability of managers and controlling shareholders to misuse corporate resources.40 Moreover, when investor protections are strong, control is more likely to be transferred through a takeover to those more able to manage the firm.41 Absent strong investor protections, the perception of agency conflicts is likely to be greater. For example, executives in firms where ownership tends to be highly concentrated earn more than at firms where control is more dispersed.42

Following the reforms introduced by SOX, acquirers have become more strategic in selecting targets. The proportion of synergy-driven deals, as measured by the relatedness of the acquisition target, has escalated since this legislation was introduced. While target shareholders experience the largest gains, acquirer shareholders also are more likely to display positive announcement date abnormal returns.43

Regulators

The SEC, Federal Trade Commission, and Department of Justice can discipline firms through formal investigations and lawsuits as outlined in Chapter 2. In 2003, the SEC approved new listing standards that would put many lucrative, stock-based pay plans to a shareholder vote. The 2010 Dodd-Frank Act requires listed firms to have fully independent compensation committees and promotes more detailed salary transparency for key managers. However, the regulatory drive for greater transparency rather than restraining outsized salary increases may be fueling the upward spiral due to how boards set CEO compensation. Boards look at CEO salaries at comparable firms, pegging salaries at levels above those offered by peer firms to attract or retain the best talent.44

Institutional Activists

Pension funds, hedge funds, private equity investors, and mutual funds have become increasingly influential in affecting the policies of companies in which they invest. Activist investors target about one in seven publicly traded firms worldwide and tend to be most prevalent in countries whose laws provide good investor protection.45

Shareholders of public firms may submit proposals to be voted on at annual meetings, but such proposals are not binding. The firm’s board can accept or reject the proposal even if approved by a majority of shareholders. Only 30% of proposals receiving majority support are implemented within 1 year of the vote.46 Nonbinding proposals approved by shareholders pertaining to takeover defenses, executive compensation, etc., are more likely to be implemented if there is an activist investor likely to threaten a proxy fight.47 When nonbinding votes are too close to call, there is evidence that firm value can increase by as much as 1.8% on the day of the vote if it passes and as much as 2.8% if it is later adopted by the firm’s board. The impact on shareholder value is even greater for firms with a substantial number of takeover defenses in place.48

Activist hedge funds during the 2008–2014 period demonstrated announcement date returns of 7% on investments in target firms, consistent with those returns observed in earlier periods. The most successful hedge funds were those willing to take minority positions in large targets mired in complicated situations. Such firms had a demonstrated track record of either changing the composition of the target’s board or getting the incumbent board to change strategic direction by using proxy contests, lawsuits, overcoming strong defenses, and replacing board members.49 Hedge fund activism often stimulates innovation by redirecting R&D investment to areas more critical to a firm’s core competencies.50 Another way in which activist hedge funds create value is by publicizing a firm as a potential takeover target. Such activism increases the likelihood that a firm will receive takeover bids.51

When institutions hold their investments for long periods of time, they play an important role in promoting good governance and in combating managers’ tendency to focus on short-term performance. As long-term investors with significant ownership stakes in the firm, they can communicate directly with management to influence decision-making and when necessary threaten to sell their shares or initiate proxy fights. They may impact decisions ranging from investment projects to dividend payouts to accounting practices. Long-term investors can improve governance by initiating or supporting shareholder proposals, improve board quality by influencing the election of board members, and affect executive turnover. By convincing the board to lower takeover defenses, they also are able to lessen management entrenchment. By helping management to prioritize investments better, long-term investors can reduce investment in both tangible and intangible assets while increasing corporate innovations measured by the number of patents and citations, as well as their significance.52

The Corporate Takeover Market

Changes in corporate control can occur because of a hostile or friendly takeover or because of a proxy contest initiated by activist shareholders. When a firm’s internal management controls are weak, the takeover market acts as a “court of last resort” to discipline bad management behavior. Strong internal governance mechanisms, by contrast, lessen the role of the takeover threat as a disciplinary factor. However, the disciplining effect of a takeover threat on a firm’s management can be reinforced when it is paired with a large shareholding by an institutional investor.53 Larger firms are more likely to be the target of disciplinary takeovers than smaller firms, and their CEOs are more likely to be replaced following a series of poor acquisitions.54 Public firms, whose management and boards tend to engage in frequent acquisitions, often overpaying, are likely to become takeover targets as their firm’s performance suffers from their undisciplined takeover and bidding practices.55

Several theories attempt to explain why managers resist a takeover attempt. The management entrenchment theory suggests that managers use takeover defenses to ensure their longevity with the firm. While relatively rare in the United States, hostile takeovers or the threat of such takeovers have historically been useful for maintaining good corporate governance by removing bad managers and installing better ones. Indeed, there is evidence of frequent management turnover even if a takeover attempt is defeated, since takeover targets are often poor financial performers. An alternative viewpoint is the shareholder interest’s theory, which suggests that management resistance to takeovers is a good bargaining strategy to increase the purchase price to the benefit of the target’s shareholders.

Proxy contests are attempts by a group of activist shareholders to gain representation on a firm’s board or to change management proposals by gaining the support of other shareholders. While those that address issues other than board representation do not bind the board, boards are becoming more responsive—perhaps reflecting fallout from the Enron-type scandals in 2001 and 2002.56 Even failed proxy contests can lead to a change in management, a restructuring of the firm, or investor expectations that the firm will be acquired.

Understanding Alternative Takeover Tactics

Implementing a friendly takeover is described briefly in the following section and in detail in Chapter 5. Hostile takeover tactics are described extensively in the following sections.

Friendly Takeovers Are Most Common

In friendly takeovers, a negotiated settlement is possible without the acquirer resorting to aggressive tactics. The potential acquirer initiates an informal dialogue with the target’s top management, and the acquirer and target reach an agreement on the key issues early in the process, such as the long-term business strategy, how they will operate in the short term, and who will be in key executive positions. Often, a standstill agreement is negotiated in which the acquirer agrees not to make any further investments in the target’s stock for a specific period. This compels the acquirer to pursue the acquisition on friendly terms, at least for the period covered by the agreement, and permits negotiations without the threat of more aggressive tactics, such as those discussed in the following sections.

Hostile Takeovers Are More a Threat Than a Reality

If initial efforts to take control of a target firm are rejected, an acquirer may choose to adopt more aggressive tactics, including the bear hug, the proxy contest, and the tender offer. However, relatively few deals reach this stage. Why? Arguably, firms are more efficient today than in the 1980s when highly diversified firms offered the likes of such corporate raiders as Carl Icahn and T. Boone Pickens opportunities to reap huge profits by breaking up such firms and selling them in pieces. The proliferation of takeover defenses has made hostile takeovers more problematic and expensive. However, the threat of an unsolicited offer turning hostile increases the likelihood the target firm’s management will negotiate a settlement. Nonetheless, hostile takeovers are relatively rare making headlines often because they are so infrequent and therefore newsworthy.

The Bear Hug: Limiting the Target’s Options

A bear hug is an offer to buy the target’s shares at a substantial premium to its current share price and often entails mailing a letter containing the proposal to the target’s CEO and board without warning and demanding a rapid decision. It usually involves a public announcement to put pressure on the board. Directors voting against the proposal may be subject to shareholder lawsuits alleging they are not working in the best interests of their shareholders. Once the bid is made public, the company is likely to attract additional bidders. Institutional investors57 and arbitrageurs add to the pressure by lobbying the board to accept the offer. By accumulating target shares, they make purchases of blocks of stock by the bidder easier, for they often are quite willing to sell their shares.

Proxy Contests in Support of a Takeover or to Gain Influence

Activist shareholders often initiate a proxy fight to remove management due to poor performance, to promote the spin-off of a business unit or the outright sale of the firm, or to force a cash distribution to shareholders. Proxy fights enable such shareholders to replace board members with those more willing to support their positions. Corporate bylaws usually are very specific about who can nominate board members to avoid frivolous nominations. For example, Apple Inc.’s bylaws in 2018 stated that only a group of no more than 20 shareholders who collectively own at least 3% of Apple’s stock can nominate a director.

Proxy contests are a means of gaining control without owning 50.1% of the voting stock, or they can be used to eliminate takeover defenses, as a precursor of a tender offer, or to oust recalcitrant target-firm board members. Air Products & Chemicals, after being rejected several times by Airgas Inc., succeeded in placing three of its own nominees on the Airgas board and, in doing so, voted to remove the chairman of Airgas, who had led the resistance to the Air Products’ offer. Notably, despite their success in electing their own nominees to the board and removing the CEO, Air Products still was unable to convince the Airgas board to accept their offer and eventually withdrew their bid. In a rare show of shareholder solidarity, activist fund Starboard Capital replaced all 12 of Darden Restaurant’s board members with its nominees following the Darden board’s failure to spin-off certain assets.

In late 2017, activist hedge fund manager, Bill Ackman, initiated a proxy contest with ADP for a board seat arguing the company could improve significantly its profit margins by automating more of its systems. Given the large number of ADP shares held by individuals and a sign of the times, Ackman conducted much of his campaign on social media such as Twitter and YouTube. Also in late 2017, in the largest corporation ever involved in a proxy battle, well-known activist investor Nelson Peltz narrowly lost in his effort to gain a seat on the board of consumer products giant Proctor & Gamble. He argued that the firm had been underperforming the overall stock market and that it had become too bureaucratic, bloated, and uncompetitive. P&G spent more than $100 million to encourage shareholders to vote against Mr. Peltz, arguing that he was not right for the board. Mr. Peltz’s Trian fund spent an estimated $25 million on his campaign. Recognizing the degree of shareholder discontent, P&G decided to add him to the board in light of his having lost by a razor thin margin of 0.1% of the more than 2 billion votes cast. While Peltz lost the proxy battle, he won the war by making it clear to P&G’s board and management that they will have to make many of the changes he was promoting.

Implementing a Proxy Contest

When the bidder is also a shareholder, the proxy process may begin with the bidder attempting to call a special shareholders meeting. Alternatively, the bidder may put a proposal to replace the board at a regularly scheduled shareholders’ meeting. Before the meeting, the bidder opens an aggressive public relations campaign, with direct solicitations sent to shareholders and an aggressive media campaign to convince shareholders to support the bidder’s proposals. The target often responds with its own campaign. Once shareholders receive the proxies, they may choose to sign and send them directly to a designated collection point such as a brokerage house or a bank. See Chapter 2 for a detailed discussion of SEC regulations governing the implementation of a proxy contest.

The Impact of Proxy Contests on Shareholder Value

Despite a low success rate, proxy fights often result in positive abnormal returns to target shareholders, regardless of the outcome. The reasons include the eventual change in management, the tendency for new management to restructure the firm, investor expectations of a future change in control, and special cash payouts made by firms with excess cash holdings. However, when management wins by a wide margin, shareholder value often declines, since little changes in how the firm is managed.58

The Hostile Tender Offer

A hostile tender offer circumvents the target’s board and management by making the offer directly to the target’s shareholders. While boards discourage unwanted bids initially, they are more likely to relent to a hostile tender offer.59 Such offers are undertaken for several reasons: (i) as a last resort if the bidder cannot get the target’s board and management to yield, (ii) to preempt another firm from making a bid for the target, and (iii) to close a transaction quickly if the bidder believes that time is critical. A common hostile takeover strategy involves acquiring a controlling interest in the target and later completing the combination through a merger. This strategy is described in detail later in this chapter.

Pretender Offer Tactics: Toehold Bidding Strategies

Toehold investments involve a potential bidder taking a less than controlling interest in a target firm. Bidders purchase stock before a formal bid to amass shares at a price less than the eventual offer price. Such purchases are secretive to avoid increasing the average price paid. For public firms, investments exceeding 5% of the target’s shares must be made public. Bidders achieve leverage with the voting rights associated with the stock purchased. The bidder also can sell this stock if the takeover attempt is unsuccessful. Once a toehold position has been established, the bidder may attempt to call a special stockholders meeting to replace the board of directors or remove takeover defenses.60

While rare in friendly takeovers, these actions are commonplace in hostile transactions, comprising about one-half of all such takeovers. In friendly deals, bidders are concerned about alienating a target firm’s board with such actions; however, in hostile situations, the target firm would have rejected the initial bid under any circumstances. The frequency of toehold bidding has declined since the early 1990s in line with the widespread adoption of takeover defenses such as poison pills and a decline in the frequency of hostile deals.61 Acquirers with a toehold investment in the target firm prior to a takeover represent about 5.4% of public firms and 1.4% of private firms. The average toehold investment size is about 31% of the target’s shares (higher in hostile deals and lower in friendly ones) and about 20% for investments made by private equity firms.

Toehold strategies may also be undertaken when a potential bidder lacks access to enough information about a target to determine a realistic offer price. The value of a toehold investment is greatest when one potential bidder has access to significantly less information than competing bidders more familiar with the target firm. Once the toehold investment is made, the more informed bidders can make offers giving the toehold investor a better idea of what constitutes a reasonable bid. However, the incentive for one bidder to make a toehold investment in advance of the bidding process is less if other potential bidders are having similar difficulty in obtaining accurate information. Furthermore, the value of the toehold investment as a means of gaining information is less when the number of potential bidders is large, as some bidders with poor information may make excessive offers for the target based on hubris rather than an accurate assessment of potential synergy.62

Implementing a Tender Offer

Tender offers can be for cash, stock, debt, or some combination. Unlike mergers, tender offers frequently use cash as the form of payment. Securities deals take longer to complete because of the need to register with the SEC, to comply with state registration requirements, and, if the issue is large, to obtain shareholder approval. If the offer involves a share exchange, it is referred to as an exchange offer. Whether cash or securities, the offer made to target shareholders may be extended for a specific period and may be unrestricted (any-or-all offer) or restricted to a certain percentage or number of the target’s shares.

In a tender offer, the bidder may buy all of the target stock that is tendered or only a portion. Those restricted to purchasing less than 100% of the target’s shares may be oversubscribed. For example, if the bidder has extended a tender offer for 70% of the target’s outstanding shares and 90% of the target’s stock actually is offered, then the bidder may choose to prorate the purchase of stock by buying only 63% (i.e., 0.7 × 0.9) of the tendered stock by each shareholder. If the bidder chooses to revise the tender offer, the waiting period is automatically extended. If another bid is made, the waiting period must also be extended another 10 days. Once initiated, tender offers for publicly firms are usually successful, although the success rate is lower if it is contested.63

Federal securities laws impose reporting, disclosure, and antifraud requirements on acquirers initiating tender offers. Once the tender offer has been made, the acquirer cannot purchase any target shares other than the number specified in the offer. Section 14(D) of the Williams Act requires that any individual or entity making a tender offer resulting in owning more than 5% of any class of equity must file a Schedule 14(D)-1 and all solicitation materials with the SEC.

Multitiered Offers

A bid can be either a one- or two-tiered offer. In a one-tier offer, the acquirer announces the same offer to all target shareholders, which provides the potential to purchase control of the target quickly and discourage other possible bidders from disrupting the deal. In a two-tiered offer, the acquirer offers to buy a number of shares at one price and more at a lower price at a later date. The form of payment in the second tier may be less attractive, consisting of securities rather than cash. The intent of the two-tiered approach is to give target shareholders an incentive to tender their shares early in the process to receive a more attractive price. Since those shareholders tendering their shares in the first tier enable the acquirer to obtain a controlling interest, their shares are worth more than those choosing to sell in the second tier.

Once the bidding firm accumulates enough shares to gain control of the target (usually 50.1%), the bidder may initiate a so-called back-end merger by calling a special shareholders meeting seeking approval for a merger, in which minority shareholders are required to accede to the majority vote. Alternatively, the bidder may operate the target firm as a partially owned subsidiary, later merging it into a newly created wholly owned subsidiary. Many state statutes require equal treatment for all tendering shareholders as part of two-tier offers and give target shareholders appraisal rights64 that allow those not tendering shares in the first or second tier to ask the state court to determine a “fair value” for the shares.65 State statutes may also contain fair-price provisions, in which all target shareholders, including those in the second tier, receive the same price and redemption rights, enabling target shareholders in the second tier to redeem their shares at a price similar to that paid in the first tier.

There are disadvantages to owning less than 100% of the target’s voting stock. These include the potential for dissatisfied minority shareholders owning significant blocks of stock to disrupt efforts to implement important management decisions and the cost incurred in providing financial statements to both majority and minority shareholders.

Comparative Success Rates

Friendly deals are the most common takeover tactic employed for good reason. According to Thomson Reuters, success rates among hostile bids and proxy contests are relatively low. For the 25 year period ending in 2016, about 40% of hostile takeover attempts resulted in a completed deal. Proxy contests that actually went to a shareholder vote concluded in a victory for the challenger approximately 26% of the time during the 5 years ending in 2016. If we include settlements between the company’s board and activist groups, those initiating the proxy fight won roughly 57% of the time during the same period. The success of proxy contests has paralleled the growth in activist hedge funds, which have grown from under $100 million in assets under management in 2000 to over $140 billion in 2016.66

Other Tactical Considerations

Successful takeovers depend on the size of the offer price premium, the board’s composition, and the makeup, sentiment, and investment horizon of the target’s current shareholders. Other factors include the provisions of the target’s bylaws and the potential for the target to implement additional takeover defenses.

The Importance of Premium, Board Composition, and Investor Sentiment

The target’s board will find it more difficult to reject offers exhibiting substantial premiums to the target’s current share price. The composition of the target’s board also influences what the board does because one dominated by independent directors may be more likely to negotiate the best price for shareholders by soliciting competing bids than to protect itself and current management. The final outcome of a hostile takeover also is dependent on the composition of the target’s ownership, how shareholders feel about management’s performance, and how long they intend to hold the stock. Firms held predominately by short-term investors (i.e., less than 4 months) are more likely to receive a bid and exhibit a lower average premium of as much as 3% when acquired. Firms held by short-term investors have a weaker bargaining position with the bidder due to the limited loyalty of such shareholders.67

To assess these factors, an acquirer compiles lists of stock ownership by category: management, officers, employees, and institutions such as pension and mutual funds. This information can be used to estimate the target’s float—total outstanding shares less shares held by insiders. The larger the share of stock held by insiders such as corporate officers, family members, and employees, the smaller the number of shares that are likely to be easily purchased by the bidder, since these types of shareholders are less likely to sell their shares.

Finally, an astute bidder will always analyze the target firm’s bylaws for provisions potentially adding to the cost of a takeover.68 Such provisions could include a staggered board, the inability to remove directors without cause, or supermajority voting requirements for approval of mergers. These and other measures are detailed later in this chapter.

Contract Considerations

To heighten the chance of a successful takeover, the bidder will include provisions in a letter of intent (LOI) to discourage the target firm from disavowing preliminary agreements. The LOI is a preliminary agreement between two companies intending to merge stipulating areas of agreement between the parties as well as their rights and limitations. It may contain features protecting the buyer; among the most common is the no-shop agreement, prohibiting the target from seeking other bids or making public information not readily available.

Contracts often grant the target and acquirer the right to withdraw from the agreement. This usually requires the payment of breakup or termination fees, sums paid to the acquirer or target to compensate for their expenses. Expenses could include legal and advisory expenses, management time, and the costs associated with opportunities that may have been lost to the bidder while involved in trying to close this deal.69 Termination fees are used more frequently for targets than acquirers because targets have greater incentives to break contracts and seek other bidders. Such fees give the target firm some leverage with the bidder. Averaging about 3% of the purchase price and found in about two-thirds of M&As, such fees result in about a 4% higher premium paid to target firms. The higher premium represents the amount paid by the bidder for “insurance” that it will be compensated for expenses incurred if the transaction is not completed and for motivating the target to complete the deal.70

Although termination fees increase the target’s cost to withdraw from a deal, there is little evidence that large fees discourage targets from accepting other bids. Deals with high termination fees are more likely to attract competing bidders. Consequently, large termination fees do not appear to prevent target management from accepting the highest bid.71 Breakup fees paid by the bidder to the target firm are called reverse breakup fees and have become more common in recent years as buyers, finding it difficult to finance transactions, have backed out of signed agreements. The stock lockup, an option granted to the bidder to buy the target firm’s stock at the first bidder’s initial offer, is another form of protection for the bidder. It is triggered whenever the target firm accepts a competing bid. Because the target may choose to sell to a higher bidder, the stock lockup arrangement usually ensures that the initial bidder will make a profit on its purchase of target stock.

Developing a Bidding Strategy

Tactics used in a bidding strategy represent a series of decision points, with objectives and options clearly identified. A poor strategy can be costly to CEOs, who may lose their jobs.72 CEOs that are disciplined bidders are less likely to be replaced than those that are not.73 Common bidding-strategy objectives include winning control of the target, minimizing the control premium, minimizing transaction costs, and facilitating post-acquisition integration.

If minimizing the purchase price and transaction costs while maximizing cooperation between the two parties is critical, the bidder may choose the “friendly” approach. This minimizes the loss of key personnel, customers, and suppliers while control is changing hands. Friendly takeovers avoid an auction environment, which may raise the target’s purchase price. Amicable deals facilitate premerger integration planning and increase the rate at which the firms can be integrated after closing.

Reading Fig. 3.2 from left to right, we see that the bidder initiates contact informally through an intermediary (sometimes called a casual pass) or through a more formal inquiry. If rejected, the bidder’s options are to walk away or become more aggressive. In the latter case, the bidder may undertake a bear hug, hoping that pressure from large institutional shareholders and arbs will nudge the target toward a negotiated settlement. If that fails, the bidder may accumulate enough shares in the open market from institutional investors to call a special shareholders meeting or initiate a proxy battle to install new board members receptive to a takeover or to dismember the target’s defenses. While generally less expensive than tender offers (which include a premium to the target’s current share price), proxy campaigns are expensive, with an average cost of $6 million, not including possible litigation costs.74 In extreme cases, the costs of proxy battles can exceed $100 million.75 If the target’s defenses are weak, the bidder may forego a proxy contest and initiate a tender offer for the target’s stock. If the target’s defenses appear formidable, the bidder may implement a proxy contest and a tender offer concurrently; however, the cost makes this option uncommon.

Fig. 3.2
Fig. 3.2 Alternative takeover tactics to negotiated settlement tender offer.

Litigation often is used to pressure the target’s board to relent to the bidder’s proposal or remove defenses and is most effective if the firm’s defenses appear to be onerous. The bidder may initiate litigation that accuses the target’s board of not giving the bidder’s offer sufficient review, or the bidder may argue that the target’s defenses are not in the best interests of the target’s shareholders. Table 3.2 summarizes common bidder objectives and the advantages and disadvantages of the various tactics that may be employed to achieve these objectives.

Table 3.2

Advantages and Disadvantages of Alternative Takeover Tactics
Common bidder strategy objectives

 Gain control of target firm

 Minimize the size of the control premium

 Minimize transactions costs

 Facilitate postacquisition integration

TacticsAdvantagesDisadvantages
Casual Pass (i.e., informal inquiry)

 May learn target is receptive to deal

 Gives advance warning

Bear Hug Offer (i.e., letter to target board forcefully proposing takeover)

 Raises pressure on target to negotiate a deal

 Gives advance warning

Open Market Purchases (i.e., acquirer buys target shares on public market)

 May lower cost of transaction

 Creates profit if target agrees to buy back bidder’s toehold position

 May discourage other bidders

 Can result in a less than controlling interest

 Limits on amount one can purchase without disclosure

 Some shareholders could hold out for higher price

 Could suffer losses if takeover attempt fails

 Could alienate target management and make a friendly takeover more difficult

Proxy Contest (i.e., effort to obtain target shareholder support to change target board)

 Less expensive than tender offer

 May obviate need for tender offer

 Relatively low probability of success if target stock widely held

 Adds to transactions costs

Hostile Tender Offer (i.e., direct offer to target shareholders to buy shares not supported by target’s board or management)

 Pressures target shareholders to sell stock

 Bidder not bound to purchase tendered shares unless desired number of shares tendered

 Tends to be most expensive tactic

 Disrupts postmerger integration due to potential loss of key target managers, customers, and suppliers

Litigation (i.e., lawsuits accusing target board of improper conduct)

 Puts pressure on target board

 Expense

Table 3.2

Activist Investors: Gaining Influence Without Control

The objective of hostile takeovers is for the acquirer to achieve control. However, the cost and complexity of implementing such deals has resulted in hostile tender offers declining in popularity. An increasingly important threat to corporate boards and management is the activist investor. They are shareholders who monitor management and board actions and influence managerial and board decisions by exercising or threatening to exercise their voting rights. Unlike hostile takeovers, the activist investor does not want control of the firm but rather to purchase enough shares to gain the attention of other investors by making their grievances well known. Once this has been achieved, the investor will promote a particular agenda designed to change a firm’s behavior to increase firm value.

Companies have become more proactive by determining where they are vulnerable and how they might minimize risk. For example, firms may spin-off or divest underperforming businesses or increase dividend payments to reduce excess cash on the balance sheet or to borrow to undertake share buybacks. Company management is now more inclined to talk to activists in an effort to keep the discussions out of the media so as not to impact the firm’s reputation or share price. The intent is to keep the discussions civil and constructive.

Activist investors who succeed in achieving their objectives do so by gaining a seat(s) on the board of the target company, giving them access to proprietary information and an opportunity to express their opinions at board meetings. Allowing such representation avoids highly public proxy fights. Unlike their predecessors, active investors in recent years are less interested in short-term gains and more interested in agitating for a specific long-term change: a change in business strategy, an increase in dividends, or a change in the composition of the firm’s board. While some efforts are successful, others go horribly wrong. In 2013, TPG-Axon was able to push out Sand Ridge Energy CEO, Tom Ward. In contrast, William Ackman lost hundreds of millions of his investors’ dollars in attempting to remove Target Corporation’s CEO. He ended up selling his stake at a loss of almost $500 million.

Firms having many takeover defenses are more likely to be targets of activist investors but are less likely to act following a nonbinding shareholder vote (e.g., to remove a poison pill). However, ownership by institutional investors raises the likelihood of management supporting the shareholder vote. But not all institutional investors act in the same manner. Banks and insurance companies are more inclined to vote against proposals to remove poison pills while ownership by mutual funds, independent investment advisors, and pension funds tend to support anti-poison pill proposals. Banks having an ongoing interest in lending to firms have traditionally supported management in shareholder votes. In contrast, pension funds often build their reputations on serving investor interests (and in some instances in supporting social causes) and can influence the voting behavior of small investors.76

Critics argue that activist investors seek to limit shareholder rights by noting their potential adverse impact on firm value when they force a board and management to focus on short-term decisions, often at the expense of long-term performance. For example, forcing a board to pay dividends to reduce cash on the balance sheet or to borrow to repurchase shares may limit the firm’s ability to pursue future high growth opportunities. However, the empirical evidence does not seem to support these claims. In a study of more than 2000 activist investments in firms between 1994 and 1997, researchers found that, on average, firms’ operating performance measured by return on assets improved relative to their industry peers during the 5 years following the activist’s investment.77 Table 3.3 provides a breakdown of common M&A related demands made by activist investors.

Table 3.3

Activist M&A-Related Demands (2010–2016)
Related toShare of total (%)
Sale of company47.4
Opposed company’s acquisition/divestiture21.9
Breakup of company16.5
Takeover bid14.2

Source: M&A Activist Insight: 2017 http://www.kingsdaleadvisors.com/resourcesdd/Kingsdale_M&A_Report.pdf.

Understanding Alternative Takeover Defenses

Takeover defenses are designed to slow down an unwanted offer or to force a suitor to raise the bid to get the target’s board to rescind the defense. They can be grouped in two categories: those put in place before receiving an offer (preoffer) and those implemented after receipt of an offer (postoffer). Given the number of alternative defenses, it is critical to understand that no individual defense is suitable for all firms at all times, because the relative costs and benefits of specific defenses depend on the firm’s unique circumstances. Table 3.4 shows the most commonly used pre- and postoffer defenses.

Table 3.4

Alternative Preoffer and Postoffer Takeover Defenses
Preoffer defensesPostoffer defenses
Poison pillsa:Greenmail (bidder’s investment purchased at a premium to what bidder paid as inducement to refrain from any further activity)
Flip-over rights plans
Flip-in rights plans
Blank check preferred stock plans
Shark repellents (implemented by changing bylaws or charter):Standstill agreements (often used in conjunction with an agreement to buy bidder’s investment)
Strengthening the board’s defenses
    Staggered or classified board elections
    “For cause” provisions
Limiting shareholder actions with respect to:
    Calling special meetings
    Consent solicitations
    Advance notice provisions
    Supermajority rules
Other shark repellents
    Antigreenmail provisions
    Fair-price provisions
    Dual class recapitalization
    Reincorporation
Golden parachutes (change of control payments)White knights
Employee stock ownership plans
Leveraged recapitalization
Share repurchase or buyback plans
Corporate restructuring
Litigation

Table 3.4

a While many different types of poison pills are used, only the most common forms are discussed in this text. Note also that the distinction between pre- and postoffer defenses is becoming murky as increasingly poison pill plans are put in place immediately following the announcement of a bid. Pills can be adopted without a shareholder vote, because they are issued as a dividend and the board has the exclusive authority to issue dividends.

Preoffer Defenses

Preoffer defenses are used to delay a change in control, giving the target firm time to erect additional defenses after the unsolicited offer has been received. Such defenses generally fall into three categories: poison pills,78 shark repellents, and golden parachutes. Table 3.5 summarizes the advantages and disadvantages of preoffer defenses.

Table 3.5

Advantages and Disadvantages of Preoffer Takeover Defenses
Type of defenseAdvantages for target firmDisadvantages for target firm
Poison pills: Raising the cost of acquisitions
Flip-over pills (rights to buy stock in the acquirer, activated with 100% change in ownership)Dilutes ownership position of current acquirer shareholders
Rights redeemable by buying them back from shareholders at nominal price
Ineffective in preventing acquisition of less than 100% of target (bidders could buy controlling interest only and buy remainder after rights expire)
Subject to hostile tender contingent on target board’s redemption of pill
Makes issuer less attractive to white knights
Flip-in pills (rights to buy target stock, activated when acquirer purchases less than 100% change in ownership)Dilutes target stock regardless of amount purchased by potential acquirer
Not given to investor who activated the rights
Rights redeemable at any point prior to triggering event
Not permissible in some states due to discriminatory nature
No poison pill provides any protection against proxy contests
Shark repellents: Strengthening the board’s defenses
Staggered or classified boardsDelays assumption of control by a majority shareholderMay be circumvented by increasing size of board, unless prevented by charter or bylaws
Limitations on when directors can be removed“For cause” provisions narrow range of reasons for removalCan be circumvented unless supported by a supermajority requirement for repeal
Shark repellents: Limiting shareholder actions
Limitations on calling special meetingsLimits ability to use special meetings to add board seats, remove or elect new membersStates may require a special meeting if a certain percentage of shareholders requests a meeting
Limiting consent solicitationsLimits ability of dissatisfied shareholders to expedite a proxy contest processMay be subject to court challenge
Advance-notice provisionsGives board time to select its own slate of candidates and to decide an appropriate responseMay be subject to court challenge
Supermajority provisionsMay be applied selectively to events such as hostile takeoversCan be circumvented unless a supermajority of shareholders is required to change provision
Other shark repellents
Antigreenmail provisionEliminates profit opportunity for raidersEliminates greenmail as a takeover defense
Fair-price provisionsIncreases the cost of a two-tiered tender offerRaises the cost to a White Knight, unless waived by typically 95% of shareholders
Dual class recapitalization/supervoting stockConcentrates control by giving “friendly” shareholders more voting power than othersDifficult to implement because requires shareholder approval and only useful when voting power can be given to pro-management shareholders
ReincorporationTakes advantage of most favorable state antitakeover statutesRequires shareholder approval; time consuming to implement unless subsidiary established before takeover solicitation
Golden parachutesEmboldens target management to negotiate for a higher premium and raises the cost of a takeover to the hostile bidderNegative public perception; makes termination of top management expensive; cost not tax deductible; subject to nonbinding shareholder vote

Table 3.5

Poison Pills (Shareholder Rights Plans and Blank Check Preferred Stock)

A poison pill involves a board issuing rights to current shareholders, with the exception of an unwanted investor, to buy the firm’s shares at an exercise price well below their current market value. Because they are issued as a dividend and the board usually has the exclusive authority to declare dividends, a pill can be adopted without a shareholder vote and implemented either before or after a hostile bid. If a specified percentage (usually 10%–20%) of the target’s common stock is acquired by a hostile investor, each right entitles the holder to purchase common stock or some fraction of participating preferred stock79 of the target firm (a flip-in pill). If a merger, consolidation, sale of at least some percentage (usually 50%) of the target’s assets, or announced tender offer occurs, the rights holder may purchase acquirer common shares (a flip-over pill). Both the flip-in and flip-over pills entitle their holders upon paying the exercise price to buy shares having a market value on the date the pill is triggered equal to some multiple (often two times) the right’s exercise price.80 Rights are redeemable at any time by the board, usually at $0.01 per right, expire after some period (sometimes up to 10 years), and trade on public exchanges.

The flip-in pill discourages hostile investors from buying a minority stake in the firm because it dilutes their ownership interest in the firm as more target shares are issued. For example, if the hostile investor buys a 20% interest in the firm and the number of target shares doubles, the investor’s ownership stake is reduced to 10%. The value of the investor’s investment also decreases as other shareholders buy more shares at a deeply discounted price. Efforts by the hostile investor to sell shares at what he or she paid are thwarted by the willingness of other shareholders, having acquired shares at a much lower price, to sell below the price paid by the hostile investor. The total cost of completing the takeover rises as the number of shares that must be acquired in a cash offer or the number of acquirer shares issued in a share exchange increases, diluting current acquirer shareholders. Similarly, the flip-over poison pill dilutes the acquirer’s current shareholders and depresses the value of their investment as more acquirer shares are issued at below their current market value.

Netflix adopted a poison pill, having both flip-in and flip-over rights, on November 2, 2012, in response to a 9.98% investment stake in the firm by investor Carl Icahn. Each shareholder, except Icahn, received a right for each common share held as of November 12, 2012, to buy one one-thousandth of a new preferred share at an exercise price of $350 per right if an investor acquires more than 10% of the firm without board approval. If triggered, each flip-in right entitled its holder to purchase by paying the right’s exercise price a number of shares of Netflix common stock having a market value of twice the exercise price (i.e., $700). At the time of the issue, Netflix common stock traded at $76 per share. Each right would be convertible into 9.2 common shares [i.e., (2 × $350)/$76] if the pill was triggered. If the firm was merged into another firm or it was to sell more than 50% of its assets, each flip-over right would entitle the holder to buy a number of common shares of the acquirer at the then-market value at twice the exercise price following payment of the $350 exercise price.

Poison pill proponents argue that it prevents a raider from acquiring a substantial portion of the firm’s stock without board permission. Since the board generally has the power to rescind the pill, bidders are compelled to negotiate with the target’s board, which could result in a higher offer price. Pill defenses may be most effective when used with staggered board defenses, because a raider would be unable to remove the pill without winning two successive elections. This increases the likelihood of the target’s remaining independent.81 Detractors argue that pill defenses simply entrench management.

Recent legal precedents further strengthen a target’s takeover defenses. The unsolicited offer by Air Products for Airgas on February 2, 2010, had been one of the longest running hostile bids in US history. After having revised up its offer twice, Air Products sought to bring this process to a close when it asked the Delaware Chancery Court to invalidate Airgas’s poison pill. On February 15, 2011, the court ruled that the board has the right to prevent shareholders from voting on the takeover offer as long as it is acting in good faith. In the wake of the court’s ruling, Air Products withdrew its bid.

The outcome of the court’s ruling has implications for future hostile takeovers. The ruling upholds Delaware’s long tradition of respecting managerial discretion as long as the board is found to be upholding its fiduciary responsibilities to the firm’s shareholders. The ruling allows target firm boards to use a poison pill as long as the board deems justified, and it is far-reaching because Delaware law governs most US publicly traded firms.

In mid-2014, the Delaware state court blocked efforts by hedge fund mogul Daniel Loeb to overturn a crucial corporate defense at legendary auction house, Sotheby. Loeb had argued that the Sotheby’s poison pill plan unfairly discriminated against his firm and inhibited his ability to wage his proxy campaign. The pill specifically limited him to no more than 10% of Sotheby’s shares while letting passive (long-term) investors hold as much as 20% of Sotheby’s shares without triggering the pill. The ruling justifies the use of such defenses to limit the ownership stake in the company of a specific investor. Sotheby had argued, and the court concurred, that it had adopted the two-tiered poison pill to protect shareholders from coercive takeover tactics. In legitimizing the two-tiered pill, the courts may have limited the future effectiveness of activist investors in some situations.

Blank check preferred stock is a class of preferred shares over which the firm’s board has the authority to determine voting rights, dividends, and conversion rights without shareholder approval. The most common reason for a firm to have such stock is to discourage an unwanted takeover of the firm. Normally a firm must amend its articles of incorporation to create such stock. Once done, the board now has the power to issue a class of preferred shares that can be converted to a substantial number of voting shares intended to increase the cost of a takeover. Other reasons for blank check preferred stock are to allow the board to quickly raise capital or as an equity contribution used in the formation of a business alliance.

Shark Repellents

Shark repellents are takeover defenses achieved by amending either a corporate charter or corporation bylaws.82 They predate poison pills as a defense, and their success in slowing down takeovers and making them more expensive has been mixed. Today, shark repellents have largely become supplements to poison pill defenses. Their primary role is to make it more difficult to gain control of the board through a proxy fight at an annual or special shareholders’ meeting. Shark repellents necessitate a shareholder vote because they require amendments to a firm’s charter. Although there are many variations of shark repellents, the most typical are staggered board elections, restrictions on shareholder actions, antigreenmail provisions, differential voting rights (DVR) shares, and debt-based defenses.

Strengthening the Board’s Defenses

Corporate directors are elected at annual shareholder meetings by a vote of the holders of a majority of shares who are present and entitled to vote. The mechanism for electing directors differs among corporations, with voting shares being cast either through a straight vote or cumulatively. With straight voting, shareholders may cast all their votes for each member of the board of directors, thereby virtually ensuring that the majority shareholder(s) will elect all of the directors. For example, assume that a corporation has four directors up for election and has two shareholders, one owning 80 shares (i.e., the majority shareholder) and one owning 20 shares (i.e., the minority shareholder). With each share having one vote, the majority shareholder will always elect the director for whom he or she casts his or her votes.

In cumulative voting systems, the number of votes each shareholder has equals the number of shares owned times the number of directors to be elected. The shareholder may cast all of these votes for a single candidate or for any two or more candidates. With cumulative voting, all directors are elected at the same time. Using the same example, the majority shareholder will have 320 votes (80 × 4), and the minority shareholder will have 80 votes (20 × 4). If the minority shareholder casts all of her votes for herself, she is assured of a seat, since the majority shareholder cannot outvote the minority shareholder for all four board seats.83

In states where cumulative voting is mandatory, companies can distribute the election of directors over a number of years to make it harder for a dissatisfied minority shareholder to gain control of the board. This makes it more difficult for the minority shareholder to elect a director when there is cumulative voting because there are fewer directors to be elected at one time. This so-called staggered or classified board election divides the firm’s directors into different classes. Only one class is up for reelection each year. A 12-member board may have directors divided into four classes, with each director elected for a 4-year period. In the first year, the three directors in what might be called “Class 1” are up for election; in the second year, “Class 2” directors are up for election; and so on. This means that a shareholder, even one who holds the majority of the stock, would have to wait for three election cycles to gain control of the board. Moreover, the size of the board is limited by the firm’s bylaws to preclude the dissatisfied shareholder from adding board seats to take control of the board.

For-cause provisions specify the conditions (e.g., fraud, regulatory noncompliance) for removing a member of the board of directors. This narrows the range of permissible reasons and limits the flexibility of dissident shareholders in contesting board seats.

Limiting Shareholder Actions

The board can restrict shareholders’ ability to gain control of the firm by bypassing the board. Limits can be set on their ability to call special shareholders’ meetings, engage in consent solicitations, and use supermajority rules (explained later). Firms frequently rely on the conditions under which directors can be removed (i.e., the “for cause” provision discussed earlier) and a limitation on the number of board seats as defined in the firm’s bylaws or charter.

Restricting the circumstances when shareholders can call special meetings effectively limits their opportunity to introduce a new slate of directors or to push for a rescission of certain defenses such as a poison pill. A firm’s bylaws often require that a new slate of directors can be nominated only at its annual meeting and restrict the ability of shareholders to call special meetings. This forces shareholders wishing to replace directors who are up for re-election only one opportunity to do so at the annual meeting. In 2016, newspaper publisher Gannett’s failure to meet a deadline for nominating directors at rival Tribune’s annual meeting meant it could not pressure the current board into accepting the firm’s hostile offer for Tribune. Why? It would be unable to mount a proxy battle to replace the Tribune’s board until the firm’s 2017 annual meeting.

In some states, shareholders may take action, without a special shareholders meeting, to add to the number of seats on the board, remove specific board members, or elect new members. These states allow dissatisfied shareholders to obtain support for their proposals simply by obtaining the written consent of shareholders through consent solicitation, a process that still must abide by the disclosure requirements applicable to proxy contests. Shareholders vote simply by responding to a mailing thereby circumventing the delays inherent in setting up a meeting to conduct a shareholder vote.84 Corporate bylaws may include advance-notice provisions requiring shareholder proposals and board nominations to be announced well in advance, sometimes as long as 2 months, of an actual vote, to buy time for management. Supermajority rules require a higher level of approval than is standard to amend the charter for transactions such as M&As. Such rules are triggered when an “interested party” acquires a specific percentage of the ownership shares (e.g., 5%–10%). Supermajority rules may require that as much as 80% of the shareholders must approve a proposed merger or a simple majority of all shareholders except the potential acquirer.

Other Shark Repellents

Other shark repellent defenses include antigreenmail provisions, fair-price provisions, DVR shares, reincorporation, and golden parachutes. These are discussed next.

Antigreenmail Provisions

Dubbed “greemail,” bidders in the 1980s profited by taking an equity position in a firm, threatening takeover, and subsequently selling their shares back to the firm at a premium over what they paid for them. Many firms have since adopted charter amendments, called antigreenmail provisions, restricting the firm’s ability to repurchase shares at a premium.

Fair-Price Provisions

Requirements that any acquirer pay minority shareholders at least a fair market price for their stock are called fair-price provisions. The fair market price may be expressed as some historical multiple of the company’s earnings or as a specific price equal to the maximum price paid when the buyer acquired shares in the company.85

Dual Class Recapitalization

A firm may create more than one class of stock to separate the performance of individual operating subsidiaries, compensate subsidiary management, maintain control, or prevent hostile takeovers. The process of creating another class of stock is called a dual class recapitalization and involves separating shareholder voting rights from cash flow rights. Voting rights indicate the degree of control shareholders have over how a firm is managed, while cash flow rights are rights to receive dividends. Shares with different voting rights, DVR shares, may have multiple voting rights (so-called supervoting shares), fractional voting rights, or no voting rights. DVR shares may have 10–100 times the voting rights of another class of stock or a fraction of a voting right per share (e.g., a shareholder might be required to hold 100 DVR shares to cast one vote). Shares without voting rights but having cash flow rights may pay a dividend higher than those with voting rights. Once approved by shareholders, the new class of stock is issued as a pro rata stock dividend or an exchange offer in which the new class of stock is offered for one currently outstanding.

Dual class structures tend to concentrate voting power as supervoting shares are issued as a pro rata dividend; later, shareholders are given the option of exchanging their supervoting shares for shares offering higher dividends, with managers retaining their supervoting shares. In dual class structures, the largest shareholder owns, on average, about 23% of the firm’s equity and about 58% of the voting rights.86 Some studies find that firm value is reduced as controlling shareholders erect excessive takeover defenses, create agency conflicts, and avoid higher risk value-enhancing investments.87 Other studies document an increase in firm value when the firm moves from a single to a dual class capital structure as controlling shareholders have more time to focus on longer-term strategies, are subject to less short-term pressure, and are more inclined to pursue higher risk growth opportunities.88 The various arguments supporting these different conclusions are discussed in more detail below.

Supervoting shares enable controlling shareholders to diversify their net worth by selling a portion of their equity in the firm without losing control. As such, insiders may be more inclined to pursue higher risk, higher return investments to improve corporate performance.89 Dual class IPOs may be particularly appropriate when the founding family or founding entrepreneur(s) are viewed as critical to the firm’s long-term performance.90 Examples include Mark Zuckerberg of Facebook and Larry Page and Sergey Brin of Google. Facebook in 2013 and Google in 2014 each issued a new class of nonvoting shares to be used for equity-based employee compensation and for financing new acquisitions out of concern about diluting the founders’ future voting power.

Dual class structures can create agency costs when controlling shareholders receive benefits not available to noncontrolling shareholders. Such benefits could include the sale of the firm’s assets to others with whom the controlling shareholders have a business relationship at a discount from their fair market value. Other benefits accruing to controlling shareholders include the sale of the firm’s products at a discount to businesses owned by the controlling shareholders or requiring the firm to pay higher than market prices to suppliers with whom the controlling shareholders have business ties. When control is concentrated insiders tend to put in place weaker boards allowing the insiders to entrench themselves and continue to receive benefits at the expense of other shareholders.91 Managers of dual class share firms also have an incentive to manipulate earnings to conceal from outside investors the full extent of the benefits they receive from having control.92

A recent highly publicized conflict between shareholders and management arose when in mid-2016 Facebook announced plans to issue as a dividend two shares of new non-voting (Class “C”) shares to current holders of Class “A” nonvoting shares and Class “B” supervoting shares (10 votes each). This would enable CEO Mark Zuckerberg to sell nonvoting Class C shares to finance philanthropic projects without surrendering control over the firm. Without the new class of stock, he would have to sell his supervoting shares to raise cash and run the risk that over time he could lose control of the firm. A class action lawsuit filed in April 2016 brought by Facebook shareholders sought to block the issuance of the new class of non-voting Class C shares. Facebook settled out of court just days before it was to go to trial on September 26, 2017 by agreeing to drop plans to create the Class C shares.

When agency problems arise at dual class structure firms the remedy often is to “unify” or convert the structure to “one share, one vote.” The elimination of the dual class structure dilutes the voting power of controlling shareholders (whose high vote shares lose their multiple voting rights) making the firm vulnerable to shareholders seeking a change in the control of the firm through proxy contests. In these instances, the firm’s market value often increases following the elimination of the dual class structure.93 Similar findings have been documented in the United Kingdom.

Most studies argue that the reduction in value for dual class structure firms is related to agency problems as holders of supervoting shares extract benefits that do not accrue to shareholders with few or no voting rights. However, the degree to which this occurs varies with the strength of corporate governance. Firms with dual class structures and with strong shareholder rights protections often exhibit increasing firm value. Why? The shareholder protections limit the ability of those with supervoting shares to exploit other classes of shareholders. Such firms allow shareholders to call special meetings, act by written consent, have no poison pill, no staggered board, and offer shareholders cumulative voting rights.94

The major US public stock exchanges allow firms to list on the exchanges with dual class shares. However, firms may not take steps to reduce the voting rights of existing shareholders in any way.95 Snapchat’s 2017 IPO took dual class structures to an extreme by issuing shares with zero voting rights causing some institutional investors to call for the outright ban on dual class shares. A compromise between the outright ban of dual class shares and one share, one vote structures is to include a “sunset” provision in IPOs. That is, supervoting shares would revert to regular common shares within 5 or 10 years after issuance or once the firm achieves a strategic milestone defined in terms of revenue or profit.96

Reincorporation

A target may change the state or country in which it is incorporated to one where the laws are more favorable for implementing takeover defenses by creating a subsidiary in the new state and later merging with the parent. Several factors need to be considered in selecting a location for incorporation, such as how the courts have ruled in lawsuits alleging breach of corporate director fiduciary responsibility in takeovers as well as the laws pertaining to certain takeover tactics and defenses. Reincorporation requires shareholder approval.

Golden Parachutes (Change-of-Control Payouts)

Employee severance packages, triggered when a change in control takes place, are called golden parachutes, which cover only a few dozen employees and terminate following a change in control. They can vary substantially with some including a lump-sum payment (often 3 years’ salary), while others extend to stock grants, options, health insurance, pension plans, consultancy arrangements, and even use of corporate jets. They are designed to raise the bidder’s acquisition cost rather than to gain time for the board. Such packages may serve the interests of shareholders by making senior management more willing to accept an acquisition.97 Golden parachutes benefit target firm shareholders by increasing the likelihood deals will be completed, but often at a lower purchase price premium.98

Golden parachutes are often associated with a reduction in firm value around their adoption date, although the incentives they create can produce ambiguous results: they may increase the chance of a takeover but destroy firm value by encouraging CEOs to accept deals not in the best interests of the firm’s shareholders. For instance, the target’s CEO may accept overvalued acquirer shares to close the deal and trigger payout of the golden parachute even though such shares are likely to decline in value.99 Actual payouts to management, such as accelerated equity awards, pensions, and other deferred compensation following a change in control, may significantly exceed the value of golden parachutes. Tax considerations and recent legislation affect corporate decisions to implement such compensation packages.100

Postoffer Defenses

Once an unwanted suitor has approached a firm, a variety of additional defenses can be introduced. These include greenmail to dissuade the bidder from continuing the pursuit; defenses designed to make the target less attractive, such as restructuring and recapitalization strategies; and efforts to place an increasing share of the company’s ownership in friendly hands by establishing employee stock ownership plans (ESOPs) or seeking white knights. Table 3.6 summarizes the advantages and disadvantages of these postoffer defenses.

Table 3.6

Advantages and Disadvantages of Postoffer Takeover Defenses
Type of defenseAdvantages for target firmDisadvantages for target firm
GreenmailEncourages raider to go away (usually accompanied by a standstill agreement)Reduces risk to raider of losing money on a takeover attempt; unfairly discriminates against nonparticipating shareholders; generates litigation; triggers unfavorable tax issues and bad publicity
Standstill agreementPrevents raider from returning for a specific time periodIncreases amount of greenmail paid to get raider to sign standstill; provides only temporary reprieve
White knightsMay be a preferable to the hostile bidderInvolves loss of target’s independence
ESOPsAlternative to white knight and highly effective if used in conjunction with certain states’ antitakeover lawsEmployee support not guaranteed; ESOP cannot overpay for stock because transaction could be disallowed by federal law
RecapitalizationsMakes target less attractive to bidder and may increase target shareholder value if incumbent management motivated to improve performanceIncreased leverage reduces target’s borrowing capacity
Share buyback plansReduces number of target shares available for purchase by bidder, arbs, and others who may sell to bidderCannot self-tender without SEC filing once hostile tender under way; reduction in the shares outstanding may facilitate bidder’s gaining control
Corporate restructuringGoing private may be an attractive alternative to bidder’s offer for target shareholders and for incumbent managementGoing private, sale of attractive assets, making defensive acquisitions, or liquidation may reduce target’s shareholder value versus bidder’s offer
LitigationMay buy time for target to build defenses and increases takeover cost to the bidderMay have negative impact on target shareholder returns

Greenmail

Greenmail involves paying a potential acquirer to leave you alone. It consists of a payment to buy back shares at a premium price in exchange for the acquirer’s agreement not to initiate a hostile takeover. In exchange for the payment, the potential acquirer is required to sign a standstill agreement, which specifies the amount of stock, if any, the investor can own and the circumstances under which the raider can sell such stock.101

White Knights and White Squires

A target may seek a white knight: another firm that is considered a more appropriate suitor. The white knight must be willing to acquire the target on terms more favorable than those of other bidders. Fearing a bidding war, the white knight often demands some protection in the form of a lockup. This may involve giving the white knight options to buy stock in the target that has not yet been issued at a fixed price or to acquire specific target assets at a fair price. Such lockups make the target less attractive to other bidders.

So called white squires are investors willing to support a firm’s board and management in the event of an unwanted takeover attempt. Unlike a white knight, which agrees to acquire the entire firm, the white squire is willing to purchase a large block of stock often at a favorable price, attractive dividend yield, and for a seat on the board. Such strategies may not be in the best interests of shareholders as they may serve only to entrench management.102 In an effort to discourage an unwanted bid from newspaper rival Gannett Corporation, Tribune Publishing sold a 12.92% stake in 2016 to billionaire entrepreneur Patrick Soon-Shiong, which is permitted under Delaware corporate law, where Tribune is incorporated.

Employee Stock Ownership Plans

ESOPs are trusts that hold a firm’s stock as an investment for its employees’ retirement program. They can be quickly set up, with the firm either issuing shares directly to the ESOP or having an ESOP purchase shares on the open market. The stock held by an ESOP is likely to be voted in support of management in the event of a hostile takeover attempt.

Leveraged Recapitalization

A firm may recapitalize by issuing new debt either to buy back stock or to finance a dividend payment to shareholders. While debt often is a means of forcing managers to focus on operating performance, it also tends to allow managers to entrench themselves.103 The additional debt reduces the firm’s borrowing capacity and leaves it in a highly leveraged position, making it less attractive to a bidder. Moreover, the payment of a dividend or a stock buyback may persuade shareholders to support the target’s management in a proxy contest or hostile tender offer.104 Recapitalization may require shareholder approval, depending on the company’s charter and the laws of the state in which it is incorporated.105

Share Repurchase or Buyback Plans

Share buybacks are used to reward shareholders, signal undervaluation, fund ESOPs, satisfy option plans, adjust capital structure, ward off takeovers, and when there are few attractive investment options. When used as a takeover defense, share buybacks reduce the number of shares that could be purchased by the potential buyer or arbitrageurs. What remains are shares held by those who are less likely to sell, namely individual investors.106 For a hostile tender offer to succeed in purchasing the remaining shares, the premium offered would have to be higher, thereby discouraging some prospective bidders. Ironically, share repurchase announcements may actually increase the probability a firm will be taken over, especially if the firm appears vulnerable to a takeover due to weak defenses or poor governance. Why? Because such firms’ share prices often underperform before buybacks and share buyback announcements call attention to their likely undervaluation.107 This is particularly true of smaller firms engaging in share repurchases.108

Corporate Restructuring

Restructuring may involve taking the company private, selling attractive assets, undertaking a major acquisition, or even liquidating the company. “Going private” typically involves the management team’s purchase of the bulk of a firm’s publicly traded shares. This may create a win-win situation for shareholders, who receive a premium for their stock, and management, who retain control. Alternatively, the target may make itself less attractive by divesting assets the bidder wants, with the proceeds financing share buybacks or payment of a special stockholder dividend. A target company also may undertake a so-called defensive acquisition to reduce excess cash balances and its current borrowing capacity. A firm may choose to liquidate the company, pay off outstanding obligations to creditors, and distribute the remaining proceeds to shareholders as a liquidating dividend. This makes sense only if the liquidating dividend exceeds what the shareholders would have received from the bidder.

Litigation

Lawsuits are common during M&As. More than 90% of large deals experience at least one lawsuit, often a class action lawsuit. In 2013, deals valued at more than $100 million experienced an average of seven shareholder lawsuits, an all-time high, up from about two per deal in 2012.109 Shareholder filed lawsuits challenged 93% of corporate mergers in 2014, up from 44% in 2007.110 Lawsuits may involve alleged antitrust concerns, violations of federal securities laws, undervaluation of the target, inadequate disclosure by the bidder as required by the Williams Act, and fraudulent behavior. Targets seek a court injunction to stop a takeover until the court has decided the merits of the allegations. By preventing a bidder from buying more stock, the target firm is buying more time to erect additional defenses.

While litigation seldom prevents a takeover, it may uncover additional information about the bidder through the discovery, or fact-finding, process that leads to more substantive lawsuits. The majority of lawsuits are settled before going to court. Bidders may sue targets to obtain shareholder mailing lists or to have takeover defensives removed. While the probability of completing deals embroiled in litigation falls by about 8%, the takeover premium for those deals that are completed increases by about 30%.111

Most Commonly Used Takeover Defenses

Table 3.7 shows the frequency with which certain types of takeover defenses are employed by firms for the largest publicly traded firms comprising the S&P 500 stock index and for the broader Russell 3000 stock index. The most common include advance notification requirements, blank check preferred stock, and the prohibition of written consent solicitation. While shareholder rights plans are relatively uncommon, the pervasiveness of blank check preferred stock enables most firms to create poison pills using such stock. While staggered or classified boards are relatively uncommon among the largest publicly traded firms, almost one-half of the firms in the Russell 3000 have such boards. Moreover, firms making up the Russell 3000 are more likely to have a greater variety of takeover defenses than larger firms in the S&P 500. This may reflect the tendency of firms that went public through an IPO to use a broader array of defenses to attract, retain and motivate good managers.

Table 3.7

Frequency of Takeover Defenses by Type for 2017
Type of takeover defenseS&P 500 firms (%)Russell 3000 (%)
Advance notification requirements9791
Blank check preferred stock9594
Written consent solicitation prohibition7172
Supermajority voting requirements4157
Limiting shareholders’ rights to call special meetings3751
Staggered board1143
Dual class capital structure  911
Flip-over or flip-in shareholder rights plans  3  5

Source: WilmerHale M&A Report https://www.wilmerhale.com/uploadedFiles/Shared_Content/Editorial/Publications/Documents/2017-WilmerHale-MA-Report.pdf.

The Impact of Takeover Defenses on Shareholder Value

Statistical outcomes are heavily dependent on the size and quality of the sample and the testing methodology employed. Small changes in sample size and the application of different statistical tests can lead to very different conclusions.112 Therefore, it should not be surprising that even the most stalwart researchers can be at odds.

Takeover Defenses and Target Firm Shareholder Financial Returns

Considerable research during the last two decades suggests that takeover defenses on average have a slightly negative impact on target firm shareholder value. However, there is evidence that the conclusions of these studies may be problematic. Why? Because variables sometimes appear to be relevant since they are proxies for variables excluded from the analysis. Recent research demonstrates that the results of these studies change significantly when other factors are considered. These factors include the presence of other state antitakeover laws, a firm’s previous defenses, and relevant court decisions.113 Other studies document specific situations in which staggered boards and poison pills can add to firm value. Some studies question whether takeover defenses even matter to shareholder value due to offsetting factors.

This section is intended to wade through the numerous recent studies attempting to address these issues. Empirical studies that find a negative return seem to support the notion that current management acts in its own interests (the management entrenchment theory), while those that find a positive return seem to support the idea that existing management acts in the best interests of shareholders (the shareholders’ interests theory). The conclusions of these competing empirical studies are discussed next.

Management Entrenchment Theory

The creation of a detailed “management entrenchment index”114 revealed that during the 1990s, firms scoring lower on the index (i.e., exhibiting lower levels of entrenchment) had larger positive abnormal returns than firms with higher scores.115 However, the close correlation between a firm’s entrenchment and abnormal returns disappeared in the 2000s, since investors had already bid up the prices of those firms that had removed takeover defenses in the 1990s and penalized those that had not.116 Another large study concluded that managers at firms protected by takeover defenses are less subject to takeover and are more likely to engage in “empire building” acquisitions that destroy firm value.117 Firm value also may be reduced because managers shielded from the threat of a hostile buyout may be under less pressure to innovate.118 Still another study found that firms moving from staggered board elections to annual elections of directors experience a cumulative abnormal return of 1.8%, reflecting investor expectations that the firm is more likely to be subject to a takeover. More recently, a study found a close positive correlation between the number of takeover defenses in place and director compensation. This suggests that directors who propose such defenses directly benefit to the extent they are insulated from activists and hostile takeovers.119

The negative impact of takeover defenses on firm value is most pronounced after judicial approval of such defenses in the 1985 landmark Delaware Supreme Court decision of Moran v. Household. The court case validated the use of poison pills giving boards of directors the sole right to adopt such measures. The court ruling further granted boards broader powers to adopt other types of takeover defenses as long as they were reasonable and wide legal discretion to reject unsolicited takeover bids. Following the ruling, firms experienced an average 5% reduction in their market value immediately following the announcement that they had adopted a poison pill. Even in the absence of a poison pill, firms adopting other measures restricting shareholder rights exhibited a decline in firm value of averaging 1.7%.120

The Moran v. Household essentially reinforced another Delaware Court ruling involving Unocal v. Mesa Petroleum also in 1985 legitimizing the two-tiered tender offer. The effect of these two court cases was to weaken the disciplinary impact of hostile takeover threats by giving boards the legal authority to reject unsolicited takeover bids. While these court cases apply directly to firms incorporated in Delaware, Delaware court decisions shape laws in other states. In fact, many states have adopted Delaware’s poison pill statutes and not a single state has invalidated the use of poison pills. In 1995, additional Delaware court rulings validated additional types of poison pills. These cases include Unitrin, Inc. v. American General Corp. and Moore Corp. v. Wallace Computer Services Inc.

An empirical analysis of family controlled S&P 500 firms documents the potential for entrenchment of family members in senior management positions if such entrenchment achieves family goals such as continued control, dividend payouts, family members among senior management, etc. Family controlled publicly traded firms are those in which members of the founder’s family are officers, directors, or block shareholders allowing for family members to impact corporate governance. As family control increases, the need for entrenchment mechanisms (e.g., poison pills) decreases. Perhaps a result of the family already having substantial control over the business through high levels of equity and voting rights which protect their positions without the need for entrenchment mechanisms.121

Shareholder Interests Theory

While it is widely believed that the Moran v. Household and Unocal v. Mesa Petroleum cases and the proliferation of poison pills contributed to management entrenchment, there is evidence that poison pills since these cases were litigated have contributed to larger takeover premiums but have had little impact on deal completion rates.122 Takeover defenses may not reduce deal completion rates, but they can reduce the chance of a bid. That is, formidable defenses discourage opportunistic bidders seeking buyouts at “bargain” prices. Therefore, the bids that are received by target firms with defenses in place are likely to be higher than they would have been had the firm been defenseless.123 The degree of target resistance to a takeover attempt enables target firm shareholders to realize higher takeover premiums than might have otherwise been the case.124 Target defenses can prove particularly effective at raising negotiated takeover premiums when the target’s management is being advised by a top-tier investment bank.125

Takeover defenses may also allow a firm’s senior management to communicate potentially negative information to investors on a more timely basis due to their feeling somewhat protected from takeover threats. The gradual release of negative information can allow the firm’s share price to adjust in a more orderly manner rather than to crash when the accumulated information is released to surprised shareholders.

A recent empirical study using a lengthy sample period (1978–2015) finds no evidence that staggered boards have a negative impact on firm value and under certain circumstances can have a significant positive impact.126 The authors contend that whether the impact of staggered boards on firm value is positive or negative depends on the situation. Staggered boards so goes the argument can create value by enabling management to focus on long-term value enhancing investments. Making it easier to change the composition of the board can disrupt the firm’s commitment to such investments. Examples of such longer-term investments could include joint product development projects with customers and strategic alliances to facilitate entry into new markets.127

Studies also show that staggered boards are effective in lowering a firm’s cost of debt128 and enable management to focus on longer term value-enhancing R&D projects.129 Staggered boards may allow for more aggressive monitoring of firm performance by board members offsetting the potential negative impact of management entrenchment on firm value. Directors may be more willing to provide more independent and perhaps controversial advice without fear of being replaced by investors with a more short-term focus.130

While the threat of corporate takeover can curb empire building and other inefficiencies, it can also create incentives for managers to focus on the short term. In contrast, managerial entrenchment can provide benefits for shareholders by allowing managers to focus more on long-term performance. Researchers have documented that entrenched managers minimize the use of accruals to manage earnings.131 Firms protected by numerous takeover defenses and committed to long-term performance (as measured by R&D spending and number of patents) are less likely to engage in earnings management than firms having relatively few defenses and are more likely to show higher firm value compared to book value.132

A recent study questions whether takeover defenses have much of an impact on shareholder value. While confirming the reduction in the frequency of hostile takeover attempts, the degree of competition for targets has remained steady during the entire auction process when measured between deal initiation and completion. Competition for takeovers, the authors argue, is now more likely to take place in private through a controlled auction process in which targets contact potential bidders, provide confidential data, and allow bidding until a winning offer is achieved. Moreover, takeover premiums have not declined over time. The researchers conclude that these findings are consistent with the shareholder interests’ hypothesis which suggests that target boards and managers are more likely to negotiate aggressively on behalf of shareholders.133 This conclusion is supported by another recent study that finds that takeover bids are most often rejected because they are of low quality and target management’s primary motive is to negotiate higher bids to increase shareholder value.134

Leveraged Recapitalizations and Target Firm Financial Returns

How investors react to the announcement of a leveraged recapitalization depends on how they assess the motives of the firm’s board and management. The shares of firms managed by poor performing managers often display decidedly negative financial returns when announcements are made that the firm is about to undertake substantial additional leverage in the wake of a takeover attempt. Financial returns can be even more negative if the potential acquirer later withdraws the offer. Investors reason that they are now stuck with both bad management and a highly leveraged firm. Shareholders of target firms with high performing managers are likely to realize less negative and often positive financial returns if the offer is withdrawn as investors anticipate that existing management will enhance value by more than the premium offered by the potential acquirer.135

Leveraged recapitalization also is a common defensive tactic in non-US firms as well, with target firms issuing debt more than twice as often as non-target firms. The tactic is more common in countries with liquid capital markets (providing easy access to inexpensive capital) and significant investor protections136 than in those countries with poorly developed capital markets and investor safeguards. Abnormal returns tend to be negative for such firms around the announcement of additional borrowing and become more negative if the takeover proposal is withdrawn. The magnitude of negative returns is less for better managed firms.137

Takeover Defenses and Public Offerings

Takeover defenses create firm value at the very point the firm is formed (i.e., an IPO) if they help the firm attract, retain, and motivate effective managers and employees and sustain business relationships. Furthermore, such defenses give the new firm time to implement its business plan fully and to invest in upgrading the skills of employees.138 The firm’s IPO value is likely to be higher when it has strong takeover defenses and large customers, dependent suppliers, and strategic partners.139 Why? Because takeover defenses tend to strengthen the firm’s business relationships with its customers, suppliers and other strategic partners since they increase the likelihood that commitments negotiated with the firm will be sustained. This “bonding” effect encourages such stakeholders to invest in their relationships with the firm: customers may increase their purchases, suppliers improve their manufacturing capabilities, and strategic partners devote more resources to the relationship.

Some Things to Remember

Corporate takeovers facilitate the allocation of resources and promote good governance by disciplining underperforming managers. Other factors external to the firm—such as federal and state legislation, the court system, regulators, and institutional activism—also serve important roles in maintaining good governance practices. Governance also is affected by the professionalism of the firm’s board of directors as well as by the effectiveness of the firm’s internal controls and incentive systems, takeover defenses, and corporate culture.

Chapter Discussion Questions

  1. 3.1 What are the management entrenchment and the shareholders’ interests’ hypotheses? Which seems more realistic in your judgment? Explain your answer.
  2. 3.2 What are the advantages and disadvantages of the friendly versus hostile approaches to a corporate takeover? Be specific.
  3. 3.3 What are the primary advantages and disadvantages of common takeover defenses?
  4. 3.4 How may golden parachutes for senior management help a target firm’s shareholders? Are such severance packages justified in your judgment? Explain your answer.
  5. 3.5 How might recapitalization as a takeover defense help or hurt a target firm’s shareholders? Explain your answer.
  6. 3.6 Anheuser-Busch (AB) rejected InBev’s all-cash offer price of $65 per share, saying it undervalued the company, despite the offer’s representing a 35% premium to AB’s preannouncement share price. InBev refused to raise its offer while repeating its strong preference for a friendly takeover. Speculate as to why InBev refused to raise its initial offer price. Why do you believe that InBev continued to prefer a friendly takeover? What do you think InBev should have done to pressure the AB board to accept the offer?
  7. 3.7 What do you believe are the primary factors a target firm’s board should consider when evaluating a bid from a potential acquirer?
  8. 3.8 If you were the CEO of a target firm, what strategy would you recommend to convince institutional shareholders to support your position in a proxy battle with the bidding firm?
  9. 3.9 Anheuser-Busch reduced its antitakeover defenses in 2006, when it removed its staggered board structure. Two years earlier, it did not renew its poison pill provision. Speculate as to why the board acquiesced in these instances. Explain how these events may have affected the firm’s vulnerability to a takeover.
  10. 3.10 In response to Microsoft’s efforts to acquire the firm, the Yahoo board adopted a “change in-control” compensation plan. The plan stated that if a Yahoo employee’s job is terminated by Yahoo without cause (i.e., the employee is performing his or her duties appropriately) or if an employee leaves voluntarily due to a change in position or responsibilities within 2 years after Microsoft acquires a controlling interest in Yahoo, the employee will receive 1 year’s salary. Yahoo notes that the adoption of the plan is an effort to ensure that employees are treated fairly if Microsoft wins control. Microsoft views the tactic as an effort to discourage a takeover. With whom do you agree, and why?

Answers to these Chapter Discussion Questions are available in the Online Instructor’s Manual for instructors using this book (https://textbooks.elsevier.com/web/Manuals.aspx?isbn=9780128150757)

End of Chapter Case Study: Strategy Matters-Sempra Energy Acquires Oncor Electric

Case Study Objectives: To Illustrate How

  •  Being the first bidder does not ensure success
  •  Learning from the mistakes of previous bidders can be a winning strategy
  •  Highly regulated industries may limit realizing potential synergy

.

Investment firms Kohlberg, Kravis & Roberts Co., Texas Pacific Group Capital, and Goldman Sachs Group Inc.’s private-equity arm directed the $45 billion (including debt) takeover of Texas Utilities (TXU) in 2007. This was the largest leveraged buyout in history. The investors believed that natural gas prices would rise; but instead, they collapsed amid a boom in US shale natural gas production. Unable to service their debt, the firm sought protection of the bankruptcy court from its creditors in early 2014. Energy Future Holdings Inc. (Energy Future), TXU’s holding company, spent more than 3 years in one of the largest-ever bankruptcy proceedings.

As part of its reorganization plan to emerge from bankruptcy court, Energy Future was trying to sell its profitable Oncor Electric Delivery Company (Oncor), operator of the largest electric transmission and distribution system in Texas. The proceeds of the sale were to be used to pay off some of the firm’s debt load. The plan also called for Energy Future to spin off its Texas Competitive Electric Holdings, an unregulated subsidiary which sells electricity competitively in the Texas electricity market, to creditors further reducing the firm’s outstanding debt. This was to be completed following the sale of Oncor. Any sale of Oncor was subject to a daunting array of regulatory and judicial hurdles. The deal needed approval of the Public Utility Commission of Texas, US Bankruptcy Court of Delaware, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, and the US Department of Justice.

Despite Energy Future’s problems, Oncor is considered a good investment by many, having posted an operating profit of $431 million in 2016. The Hunt family of Texas wanted to buy Oncor and put its assets into a real-estate investment trust, but this was not acceptable to regulators leery of the loss of tax revenue and the family’s limited utility industry expertise. The Hunt family also would not agree to share some of the take savings with Oncor’s customers. Then NextEra Energy Inc., a Fortune 200 largely East Coast electric utility, tried to buy Oncor based on their expertise in managing utilities, but they would not commit to the “ring-fencing”140 of Oncor required by state regulators feeling uneasy after TXU’s collapse.

Three months after the Nextra proposal collapsed, Warren Buffett’s Berkshire Hathaway Inc. (Berkshire) made a $9 billion bid, which was lower than previous suitors. Oncor was to be included in Berkshire’s thriving electric utility operations. While the regulators were supportive of the Berkshire proposal, some creditors were not. Elliott Management (Elliott), the biggest creditor of Energy Future (the entity that controls Oncor), expressed interest in putting together a rival bid. Elliott had purchased a considerable amount of Oncor’s debt at a steep discount from its face value. With Elliott opposed to the Berkshire proposal, it would have been very difficult to get creditors to agree to a reorganization plan that would allow Energy Future to emerge from bankruptcy.

Within 3 weeks of Berkshire’s bid Sempra Energy (Sempra) submitted a higher bid. Sensing that it would recover a larger portion of what it was owed by Energy Future, Elliott agreed to support the Sempra bid. Berkshire said it would not raise its bid, as Warren Buffett has a history of avoiding bidding wars, and withdrew its offer in the face of Elliott’s opposition.

Sempra’s August 20, 2017 proposal involved buying Energy Future, the indirect owner of 80% of Oncor, in an all-cash deal valued at $9.45 billion. Sempra will also assume responsibility for $9.35 billion in Oncor’s debt bringing the enterprise value to $18.8 billion. The deal is expected to augment Sempra’s 2018 earnings and to expand the firm’s growth in the Texas energy market and Gulf Coast region. Energy Future’s board favored Sempra’s bid after it received assurances it would get approval by the Public Utility Commission of Texas, as well as the US bankruptcy court judge. Postclosing, Sempra will own 64% of Oncor. The decision on who would buy Oncor came down to the offer price and who could get agreement among the creditors and the bankruptcy court judge, as well as gain regulatory approval.

Oncor, which as part of Energy Future has been embroiled in Chapter 11 bankruptcy, should see its credit rating improve due to the financial strength of the new parent. Sempra will maintain the existing independence of the Oncor board of directors which has served to protect the interests of Oncor and its customers during the ongoing Energy Future bankruptcy proceedings. This decision heightened the likelihood that the deal would receive regulatory approval. Sempra has committed to support Oncor’s plan to invest $7.5 billion over 5 years to expand and improve its transmission and distribution network.

The takeover left Sempra with a debt to equity ratio well above the industry average possibly limiting its ability to finance future investment opportunities. Its commitment to spend $7.5 billion over the next 5 years will further erode cash available for alternative investments. Because the firm was short of cash at the time of the bid, it required an equity contribution from an outside partner, thereby diluting its ownership stake in Energy Future. Finally, unlike other previous suitors, Sempra was willing to accept an independent board structure for Oncor, consisting mostly of outside directors. The question remains: Did Sempra concede too much to acquire an ownership interest in Oncor? Only time will tell.

Discussion Questions

  1. 1. What decisions made by Sempra Energy could affect its control over Oncor?
  2. 2. Describe the takeover tactics employed by each previous suitor and why they failed? What enabled Sempra to win approval?
  3. 3. What constituencies won and which lost with Sempra’s takeover of Oncor?
  4. 4. Is the highest bid necessarily the best bid? Explain your answer.
  5. 5. Compare and contrast the Sempra and Berkshire Hathaway bids for Oncor?
  6. 6. Describe the unique challenges of buying an electric utility out of bankruptcy? Illustrate how these challenges were overcome by Sempra Energy? Be Specific.
  7. 7. The case study states the following: Sempra learned from the failures of past bidders to gain regulatory approval. But these concessions came with a price. What is that price? Be specific.

Answers to these questions are found in the Online Instructor’s Manual available to instructors using this book (https://textbooks.elsevier.com/web/Manuals.aspx?isbn=9780128150757).

References

Adams R., Akyol A., Verwijmeren P. Director skill sets. J. Financ. Econ. 2018;130:641–662.

Ahn S., Shrestha K. The differential effects of classified boards on firm value. J. Bank. Financ. 2013;37:3993–4013.

Amihud Y., Stoyanov S. Do staggered boards harm shareholders?. J. Financ. Econ. 2017;123:432–439.

Armstrong C., Core J.E., Guay W.R. Do independent directors cause improvements in firm transparency?. J. Financ. Econ. 2014;113:383–403.

Atanassov J. Do hostile takeovers stifle innovation? Evidence from antitakeover legislation and corporate patenting. J. Financ. 2013;68:1097–1131.

Baugess S., Slovin M., Sushka M. Large shareholder diversification, corporate risk taking, and the benefits of changing to differential voting rights. J. Bank. Financ. 2012;36:1244–1253.

Baran L., Forst A. Disproportionate insider control and board of director characteristics. J. Corp. Finan. 2015;35:62–80.

Bargeron L., Lehn K., Smith J. Employee–management trust and M&A activity. J. Corp. Finan. 2015;35:389–406.

Bartlett, R., Talley, E., 2017. Law and corporate governance. In: The Handbook of the Economics of Corporate Governance. North Holland Publishing Company, Amsterdam, vol. 1, pp. 177–234.

Basuil D., Datta D. Value creation in cross-border acquisitions: the role of outside directors' human and social capital. J. Bus. Res. 2017;80:35–44.

Bates T., Becher D. Bid resistance by takeover targets: managerial bargaining or bad faith. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 2017;52:837–866.

Baulkaran V. Management entrenchment and the valuation discount of dual class firms. Q. Rev. Econ. Finance. 2014;54:70–81.

Bebchuk L., Coates J., Subramanian G. The powerful anti- takeover force of staggered boards: theory, evidence, and policy. Stanford Law Rev. 2002;54:887–951.

Bebchuk L., Fried J. Executive compensation as an agency problem. J. Econ. Perspect. 2003;17:71–92.

Bebchuk L., Fried J. Pay Without Performance: The Unfulfilled Promise of Executive Compensation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press; 2004.

Bebchuk L., Cohen A., Wang C. Learning and the disappearing association between governance and returns. J. Financ. Econ. 2010;102:199–221.

Bebchuk L., Brav A., Jiang W. The long-term effects of hedge fund activism. Columbia Law Rev. 2015;115:1085–1156.

Bebchuk L., Cohen A., Wang C. Golden parachutes and the wealth of shareholders. J. Corp. Finan. 2014;25:140–154.

Bebchuk, L., Cohen, A., 2017. Recent Board Declassifications: A Response to Cremers and Sepe. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2970629https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2970629.

Bernile G., Bhagwat V., Yonker S. Board diversity, firm risk, and corporate policies. J. Financ. Econ. 2018;127:588–612.

Betton S., Eckbo B., Thorburn K. Merger negotiations and the toehold puzzle. J. Financ. Econ. 2009;91:158–178.

Bhabra H., Hossain A. The impact of SOX on the returns and acquirers in corporate tender offers. N. Am. J. Econ. Financ. 2017;42:1–19.

Bhagat S., Dong M., Hirshleifer D., Noah R. Do tender offers create value? New methods and evidence. J. Financ. Econ. 2005;76:3–60.

Bhojraj S., Sengupta P., Zhang S. Takeover defenses: entrenchment and efficiency. J. Account. Econ. 2017;63:142–160.

Bogle J. Reflections on “toward a common sense and common ground”. Iowa J. Corp. Law. 2007;33:31.

Boyson N., Gantchev N., Shivdasani A. Activism mergers. J. Financ. Econ. 2017;126:54–73.

Brav A., Jiang W., Ma S., Tian X. How does hedge fund activism reshape corporate innovation. J. Financ. Econ. 2018;130:237–264.

Burkart M., Gromb D., Mueller H., Panunzi F. Legal investor protections and takeovers. J. Financ. 2014;69(3):1139–1165.

Cain M., McKeon S., Solomon S. Do takeover laws matter? Evidence from five decades of hostile takeovers. J. Financ. Econ. 2017;124:464–485.

Chakravarty S., Rutherford L. Do busy directors influence the cost of debt? An examination trhough the lens of takeover vulnerability. J. Corp. Finan. 2017;43:42–443.

Chang Y., Chou R., Huang T. Corporate governance and the dynamics of capital structure: new evidence. J. Bank. Financ. 2015;48:374–385.

Chemmanur T., Jiao Y. Dual-class IPOs: a theoretical analysis. J. Bank. Financ. 2012;36:305–319.

Chen D. Classified boards, the cost of debt, and firm performance. J. Bank. Financ. 2012;36:3346–3365.

Chen S., Hsu C., Huang C. The white squire defense: evidence from private investments in public equity. J. Bank. Financ. 2016;64:16–35.

Cohen A., Wang C. How do staggered boards affect shareholder value? Evidence from a natural experiment. J. Financ. Econ. 2013;110:627–641.

Cohen A., Wang C. Reexamining staggered boards and shareholder value. J. Financ. Econ. 2017;125:637–647.

Cremers M., Nair V. Governance mechanisms and equity prices. J. Financ. 2005;60:2859–2894.

Cremers M., Ferrell A. Thirty years of shareholders rights. J. Financ. 2014;69:1167–1196.

Cremers M., Litov L., Sepe S. Staggered boards and long-term value, revisited. J. Financ. Econ. 2017;1–23.

Cunat V., Gine M., Guadalupe M. The vote is cast: the effect of corporate governance on shareholder value. J. Financ. 2012;67:1943–1977.

Dahya J., Golubov A., Petmezas D., Travlos N. Governance mandates, outside directors, and acquisition performance. J. Corp. Finan. 2018 (Forthcoming).

Dai R., Massoud N., Nandy D., Saunders A. Hedge funds in M&A deals: is there exploitation of insider information?. J. Corp. Finan. 2017a;47:23–45.

Dai L., Dharwadkar R., Shi L., Zhang B. The governance transfer of blockholders: evidence from block acquisitions and earnings management around the world. J. Corp. Finan. 2017b;45:586–607.

Davidoff S., Cain M. Takeover Litigation in 2013. January 9 http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2377001. 2014.

Di Meo F., Lara J., Surroca J. Managerial entrenchment and earnings management. J. Account. Public Policy. 2017;36:399–414.

Dimopoulos T., Sacchetto S. Preemptive bidding, target resistance, and takeover premiums. J. Financ. Econ. 2014;114:444–480.

Dow J. Boards, CEO entrenchment, and the cost of capital. J. Financ. Econ. 2013;110:680–695.

Drobetz W., von Meyerinck F., Oesch D., Schmid M. Industry expert directors. J. Bank. Financ. 2018;92:195–215.

Duru A., Wang D., Zhao Y. Staggered boards, corporate opacity, and firm value. J. Bank. Financ. 2013;37:341–360.

Edmans, A., Holderness, C., 2017. Blockholders: a survey of theory and evidence. In: The Handbook of the Economics of Corporate Governance. North Holland Publishing Company, Amsterdam, vol. 1, pp. 541–636.

El-Khatib R., Fogel K., Jandik T. CEO network centrality and merger performance. J. Financ. Econ. 2015;110:349–382.

Elson C., Ferrere C. Peer groups: understanding CEO compensation and a proposal for a new approach. In: Director Notes; The Conference Board; 2013.

Ertimur Y., Ferri F., Stubben S. Board of directors responsiveness to shareholders: evidence from shareholder proposals. J. Corp. Finan. 2010;16:53–72.

Ertugrul M. Bargaining power of targets: takeover defenses and top-tier target advisors. J. Econ. Bus. 2015;78:48–78.

Feito-Ruiz I., Renneboog L. Takeovers and (excess) CEO compensation. J. Int. Financ. Mark. Inst. Money. 2017;50:156–181.

Ferreira M., Massa M., Matos P. Shareholders at the gate? Institutional investors and cross-border mergers and acquisitions. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2010;23:601–644.

Ferris S., Houston R., Javakhadze D. Friends in the right places: the impact of political connections on corporate merger activity. J. Corp. Finan. 2016;41:81–102.

Fich E., Tran A., Walkling R. On the importance of golden parachutes. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 2013;48:1717–1753.

Fich E., Rice E., Tran A. Contractual revisions in compensation: evidence of merger bonuses to target CEOs. J. Account. Econ. 2016;61:338–368.

Field L., Mkrtchyan A. The effect of director experience on acquisition performance. J. Financ. Econ. 2017;123:488–511.

Fralich R., Papadopoulos A. The financial crisis, acquisition premiums, and the moderating effect of CEO power. Long Range Plan. 2017;51:204–218.

Francis T., Lublin J. CEO pay depends on board’s independence, study finds. Wall Street J. 2016 March 9.

Gantchev N. The costs of shareholder activism: evidence from a sequential decision model. J. Financ. Econ. 2013;107:610–631.

Gaspara J., Massa P. Shareholder investment horizons and the market for corporate control. J. Financ. Econ. 2005;76:135–165.

Gine M., Moussawi R., Sedunov J. Governance mechanisms and effective activism: evidence from shareholder proposals on poison pills. J. Empir. Financ. 2017;43:185–202.

Goktan M., Kieschnick R. A target’s perspective on the effects of ATPs in takeovers after recognizing its choice in the process. J. Corp. Finan. 2012;18:1088–1103.

Golbe D., Nyman I. How do share repurchases affect ownership concentration?. J. Corp. Finan. 2013;20:22–40.

Gompers P., Ishii J., Metrick A. Extreme governance: an analysis of U.S. dual-class companies in the United States. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2010;23:1051–1088.

Govindarajan V., Srivastava A. Reexamining dual class stock. Bus. Horiz. 2018;61:461–466.

Guthrie K., Sokolowsky J., Wan K. Compensation and board structure revisited. J. Financ. 2012;67:1149–1169.

Gupta K., Krishnamurtia C., Tourani-Rad A. Financial development, corporate governance, and cost of equity. J. Contemp. Account. Econ. 2018;14:65–82.

Harford J., Schonlau R. Does the director labor market offer ex post setting-up for CEOs? The case of acquisition. J. Financ. Econ. 2013;110:18–36.

Harford J., Kecskes A., Mansi S. Do long-term investors improve corporate decision making?. J. Corp. Finan. 2018;50:424–452.

Hauser R. Busy directors and firm performance: evidence from mergers. J. Financ. Econ. 2018;128:16–37.

Heron R., Lie E. The effect of poison pill adoptions and court rulings on firm entrenchment. J. Corp. Finan. 2015;35:286–296.

Hilscher J., Sisli-Ciamarra E. Conflicts of interest on corporate boards: the effect of creditor-directors on acquisitions. J. Corp. Finan. 2013;19:140–158.

Hoffman L. Professor takes his issues with merger lawsuits to court. Wall Street J. 2015 July 28.

Hotchkiss E., Qian J., Song W. Holdup, Renegotiation, and Deal Protection in Mergers. 2005 Boston College: Working Paper.

Howell J. The survival of the U.S. dual class share structure. J. Corp. Finan. 2017;44:440–450.

Huang J., Jiang F., Lie E., Yang K. The role of investment banker directors in M&A. J. Financ. Econ. 2014;112:269–286.

Huang C. Takeover vulnerability and the credibility of signaling: the case of open-market share repurchases. J. Bank. Financ. 2015;58:405–417.

Jacobsen S. The death of the deal: are withdrawn acquisition deals informative of CEO quality?. J. Financ. Econ. 2014;114:54–83.

Jandik T., Lallemand J. Value impact of debt issuances by targets of withdrawn takeovers. J. Corp. Finan. 2015;29:475–494.

Jandik T., Lallemand J., McCumber W. The value implications of target debt issuance in withdrawn takeovers: what role do country specific M&A regulations play?. J. Multinatl. Financ. Manag. 2017;40:14–32.

Jeon J., Ligonb J.A. How much is reasonable? The size of termination fees in mergers and acquisitions. J. Corp. Finan. 2011;17:959–981.

Johnson W., Karpoff J., Yi S. The bonding hypothesis of takeover defenses: evidence from IPO firms. J. Financ. Econ. 2015;117:307–332.

Jordan B., Kim S., Liu M. Growth opportunities, short-term market pressure, and dual class shares. J. Corp. Finan. 2016;41:304–328.

Kalodimos J., Lundberg C. Shareholder rights in mergers and acquisitions: are appraisal rights being abused?. Financ. Res. Lett. 2017;22:53–57.

Kang J., Luo J., Na H. Are institutional investors with multiple blockholdings effective monitors?. J. Financ. Econ. 2018;128:576–602.

Karpoff J., Wittry M. Institutional and legal context in natural experiments: the case of state antitakeover laws. J. Financ. 2018;73:657–714.

Kim H., Liao R., Wang Y. Active block investors and corporate governance around the world. J. Int. Financ. Mark. Inst. Money. 2015;39:181–194.

Kirsch A. The gender composition of corporate boards: a review and research agenda. Leadersh. Q. 2018;29:346–364.

Krolikowski M. Incentive pay and acquirer returns—the impact of Sarbanes-Oxley. Q. Rev. Econ. Finance. 2016;59:99–111.

Krishnan C., Masulis R.W., Thomas R.S., Thompson R.B. Stakeholder litigation in mergers and acquisitions. J. Corp. Finan. 2012;18:1248–1268.

Krishnan C., Partnoy F., Thomas R. The second wave of hedge fund activism: the importance of reputation, clout, and expertise. J. Corp. Finan. 2016;40:296–314.

Lahlou I., Navatte P. Director compensation incentives and acquisition performance. Int. Rev. Financ. Anal. 2017;53:1–11.

Larrain B., Tapia M., Urzua F. Investor protection and corporate control. J. Corp. Finan. 2017;47:174–190.

Lauterbach B., Pajuste A. The long-term valuation effects of voluntary dual class share unifications. J. Corp. Finan. 2015;31:171–185.

Lehn K., Zhao M. CEO turnover after acquisitions: are bad bidders fired?. J. Financ. 2006;61:1383–1412.

Levi M., Li K., Zhang F. Director gender in mergers and acquisitions. J. Corp. Finan. 2014;28:185–200.

Levit D., Malenko N. Non-binding voting for shareholder proposals. J. Financ. 2012;66:1579–1614.

Levit D. Advising shareholders in takeovers. J. Financ. Econ. 2017;126:614–634.

Li D., Eden L., Josefy M. Agent and task complexity in multilateral alliances: the safeguarding role of equity governance. J. Int. Manag. 2017a;23:227–241.

Li D., Chen Z., An Z., Murong M. Do financial analysts play a role in shaping the rival response of target firms? International evidence. J. Corp. Finan. 2017b;45:84–103.

Lin J., Stephens C., Wu Y. Limited attention, share repurchases, and takeover risk. J. Bank. Financ. 2014;42:283–301.

Listokin Y. Corporate voting versus market price setting. Am. Law Econ. Rev. 2009;11:608–637.

Liu T., Mulherin J. How has takeover competition changed over time?. J. Corp. Finan. 2018;49:104–119.

Masulis R., Wang C., Xie F. Corporate governance and acquirer returns. J. Financ. 2007;62:1851–1890.

Masulis R., Mobbs S. Independent director incentives: where do talented directors spend their limited time and energy?. J. Financ. Econ. 2014;111:408–429.

Mehrotra V., Morck R. Governance and stakeholders. In: The Handbook of the Economics of Corporate Governance. 637–683. 2017;vol. 1.

Miletkov M., Poulsen A., Wintoki M. The role of corporate bard structure in attracting foreign investors. J. Corp. Finan. 2014;29:143–157.

Neyland J., Shekhar C. How much is too much? Large termination fees and target distress. J. Bank. Financ. 2018;88:97–112.

Nguyen N. On the compensation and activity of corporate boards. J. Corp. Finan. 2014;29:1–19.

Obermann J., Velte P. Determinants and consequences of compensation-related shareholder activism and say on pay votes: a literature review and research agenda. J. Account. Lit. 2018;40:116–151.

Offenberg D. Firm size and the effectiveness of the market for corporate control. J. Corp. Finan. 2009;15:66–79.

Povel P., Sertsios G. Getting to know each other: the role of toeholds in acquisitions. J. Corp. Finan. 2014;26:201–224.

Randolph R., Wang Z., Memili E. Entrenchment in publicly traded family firms: evidence from the S&P 500. Long Range Plan. 2018;51:736–749.

Rhahman M. Do managerial behaviors trigger firm exit? The case of hyperactive bidders. Q. Rev. Econ. Finance. 2013;54:92–110.

Rau R., Xu J. How do ex ante severance pay contracts fit into optimal executive incentive schemes. J. Account. Res. 2013;51:631–671.

Rossi S., Volpin P. Cross country determinants of mergers and acquisitions. J. Financ. Econ. 2004;74:277–304.

Sanchez-Marin G., Lozano-Reina G., Samuel Baixauli-Soler J., Encarnacion Lucas-Perez M. Say on pay effectiveness, corporate governance mechanisms, and CEO compensation alignment. Bus. Res. Q. 2017;20:226–239.

Schmidt B. Costs and benefits of friendly boards during mergers and acquisitions. J. Financ. Econ. 2015;117:424–447.

Souther M. The effects of takeover defenses: evidence from closed end funds. J. Financ. Econ. 2016;119:420–440.

Stout L. Do antitakeover defenses decrease shareholder wealth? The ex post/ex ante valuation problem. Stanford Law Rev. 2002;55:845–861.

Tinaikar S. Executive compensation and private control benefits: a comparison of US and Canadian dual class firms. J. Int. Account. Audit. Tax. 2017;29:32–51.

Yim S. The acquisitiveness of youth: CEO age and acquisition behavior. J. Financ. Econ. 2013;108:250–273.

Zhao J. Entrenchment or incentive? CEO employment contracts and acquisition decisions. J. Corp. Finan. 2013;22:124–152.


1 Gupta et al. (2018).

2 Mehrotra and Morck (2017).

3 Hilscher and Sisli-Ciamarra (2013).

4 Miletkov et al. (2014).

5 Field and Mkrtchyan (2017).

6 Basuil and Datta (2017).

7 Drobetz et al. (2018).

8 Armstrong et al. (2014) find that firm value is positively influenced by outsider-dominated boards. Dahya et al. (2018) document that in the UK, acquirers whose boards are dominated by outside directors show higher returns when targets are public than when they are private. Why? Because outside director effectiveness may be better when access to information is greater as often is the case with private targets.

9 Francis and Lublin (2016).

10 Fralich and Papadopoulos (2017).

11 Leung et al. (2018).

12 Yim (2013).

13 Kirsch (2018).

14 Levi et al. (2014).

15 Guthrie et al. (2012).

16 Schmidt (2015).

17 Masulis and Mobbs (2014). Chakravarty and Rutherford (2017) find that “busy” directors (protective of their board positions) are more inclined to promote antitakeover defenses which may lower the likelihood of takeover and limit potential violation of current loan covenants. Such actions can reduce the cost of borrowing.

18 Hauser (2018).

19 El-Khatib et al. (2015).

20 Ferris et al. (2016).

21 Dow (2013).

22 Fich et al. (2016).

23 Harford and Schonlau (2013).

24 Huang et al. (2014).

25 Lahlou and Navatte (2017), Nguyen (2014).

26 Feito-Ruiz and Renneboog (2017).

27 Kang et al. (2018).

28 Bernile et al. (2018).

29 Adams et al. (2018).

30 Levit (2017).

31 Sanchez-Marin et al. (2017). For a literature review of “say on pay” research, see Obermann and Velte (2018).

32 Krolikowski (2016).

33 For an excellent discussion of block holders, see Edmans and Holderness (2017).

34 Dai et al. (2017a,b).

35 Bebchuk and Fried (2003, 2004).

36 Rau and Xu (2013).

37 Zhao (2013).

38 Bargeron et al. (2015).

39 The SEC itself has delegated certain responsibilities for setting accounting standards to the not-for-profit Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB).

40 Burkart et al. (2014).

41 Larrain et al. (2017).

42 Tinaikar (2017).

43 Bhabra and Hossain (2017).

44 Elson and Ferrere (2013).

45 Kim et al. (2015).

46 Ertimur et al. (2010).

47 Levit and Malenko (2012).

48 Cunat et al. (2012).

49 Krishnan et al. (2016).

50 Brav et al. (2018).

51 Boyson et al. (2017).

52 Harford et al. (2018a,b).

53 Cremers and Nair (2005).

54 Offenberg (2009).

55 Rhahman (2013).

56 According to Ertimur et al. (2010), boards implemented 41% of nonbinding shareholder proposals for majority voting in 2004, versus only 22% in 1997.

57 Institutional investors include insurance companies, pension funds, hedge funds, banks, and mutual funds and account, on average, for more than two-thirds of the shareholdings of publicly traded firms (Bogle, 2007).

58 Listokin (2009).

59 In a study of 1,018 tender offers in the United States between 1962 and 2001, Bhagat et al. (2005) found that target boards resisted tender offers about one-fifth of the time. In a study of 49 countries, Rossi and Volpin (2004) found that only about 1% of 45,686 M&A deals between 1990 and 2002 were opposed by target boards.

60 When such a meeting can be called is determined by the firm’s articles of incorporation, governed by the laws of the state in which the firm is incorporated. A copy of a firm’s articles of incorporation can usually be obtained from the Office of the Secretary of State of the state in which the firm is incorporated.

61 Betton et al. (2009).

62 Povel and Sertsios (2014).

63 According to FactSet Mergerstat, the success rate of total attempted tender offers between 1980 and 2000 was more than 80%, with the success rate for uncontested offers more than 90% and for contested offers (i.e., by the target’s board) slightly more than 50%.

64 In 2015, Delaware’s Court of Chancery had 43 appraisal lawsuits filed, up from 16 the prior year. The majority of the plaintiffs settled for a small increase in the value of their target shares. While appraisal rights can be abused by opportunistic target shareholders in an effort to gain more than fair value for their shares, such instances appear to be relatively rare (Kalodimos and Lundberg, 2017).

65 The minority shares may be subject to a “minority discount,” since they are worth less to the bidder than those acquired in the process of gaining control.

66 Bartlett and Talley (2017).

67 Gaspara and Massa (2005).

68 Unlike charters, which are recorded in the Office of the Secretary of State in the state in which the firm is incorporated, corporate bylaws generally are held by the firm along with other corporate records and may be available through the firm’s website or by requesting a copy directly from the firm.

69 Hotchkiss et al. (2005).

70 Jeon and Ligonb (2011).

71 Neyland and Shekhar (2018).

72 Lehn and Zhao (2006) found that 47% of acquiring firm CEOs were replaced within 5 years.

73 Jacobsen (2014).

74 Gantchev (2013).

75 In late 2017, Proctor & Gamble spent more than $100 million to thwart activist investor Nelson Peltz’s effort to gain a board seat. Mr. Peltz’s firm Trian is rumored to have spent as much as $25 million.

76 Gine et al. (2017).

77 Bebchuk et al. (2015).

78 Poison pills could be viewed as postoffer defenses, since they can be implemented after an offer has been made.

79 The fraction of a preferred share is intended to give the shareholder about the same dividend, voting, and liquidation rights as would one common share and should approximate the value of one common share.

80 The exercise price is determined by estimating the long-term trading value of the company’s common shares during the life of the plan. The greater the exercise price relative to the market value of the firm’s share price, the greater the number of new shares a rights holder can buy once he or she pays the exercise price.

81 Bebchuk et al. (2002).

82 The charter gives the corporation its legal existence and consists of the articles of incorporation, a document filed with a state government by the founders of a corporation, and a certificate of incorporation, a document received from the state once the articles have been approved. The corporation’s powers thus derive from the laws of the state and from the provisions of the charter. Rules governing the internal management of the corporation are described in the corporation’s bylaws, which are determined by the corporation’s founders.

83 While there are many possible combinations, if the majority shareholder was to cast 81 votes for each of three seats, he would have only 77 votes remaining (i.e., 320–243) for the last seat. As the number of directors increases, it becomes easier for the minority shareholder to win a seat (or seats), since the majority shareholder’s votes must be spread over more directors to block the minority shareholder.

84 Whereas the winning vote in a proxy fight is determined as a percentage of the number of votes actually cast, the winning vote in a consent solicitation is determined as a percentage of the number of shares outstanding. A dissatisfied shareholder may find it easier to win a proxy contest because many shareholders simply do not vote.

85 In two-tiered tender offers, the fair-price provision forces the bidder to pay target shareholders who tender their stock in the second tier the same terms offered to those tendering their stock in the first tier.

86 Baulkaran (2014).

87 Gompers et al. (2010).

88 Jordan et al. (2016).

89 Baugess et al. (2012), Ferreira et al. (2010).

90 Chemmanur and Jiao (2012).

91 Baran and Forst (2015).

92 Li et al. (2017a,b).

93 Lauterbach and Pajuste (2015).

94 Li et al. (2017a,b).

95 Howell (2017).

96 Govindarajan and Srivastava (2018).

97 Fich et al. (2016).

98 Fich et al. (2013).

99 Bebchuk et al. (2014).

100 The 1986 Tax Act imposed penalties on these types of plans if they create payments that exceed three times the employee’s average pay over the previous 5 years and treats them as income and thus not tax-deductible by the paying corporation. More recently, the Dodd–Frank bill of 2010 gives shareholders the opportunity to express their disapproval of golden parachutes through a nonbinding vote.

101 Courts view greenmail as discriminatory because not all shareholders are offered the opportunity to sell their stock back to the target firm at an above-market price. Nevertheless, courts in some states (e.g., Delaware) have found it appropriate if done for valid business reasons. Such reasons could include the need for the firm to stay focused on implementing its business strategy. Courts in other states (e.g., California) have favored shareholder lawsuits, contending that greenmail breaches fiduciary responsibility.

102 Chen et al. (2016).

103 Chang et al. (2015).

104 The primary differences between a leveraged recapitalization and a leveraged buyout are the firm remains a public company and that management does not take an equity stake in the firm in a leveraged recapitalization.

105 Shareholders will benefit from the receipt of a dividend or from capital gains resulting from a stock repurchase. The increased interest expense shelters some of the firm’s taxable income and may encourage management to improve the firm’s performance. Thus, current shareholders may benefit more from this takeover defense than from a hostile takeover of the firm.

106 Share buybacks make firm ownership less concentrated as large shareholders such as institutional investors, perhaps showing a greater preference for liquidity, appear to be more likely to participate in buybacks than individual shareholders (Golbe and Nyman, 2013).

107 Huang (2015).

108 Lin et al. (2014).

109 Davidoff and Cain (2014).

110 Hoffman (2015), July 28.

111 Krishnan et al. (2012).

112 Cohen and Wang (2017).

113 Karpoff and Wittry (2018).

114 Bebchuk et al. (2002) created a management entrenchment index in an effort to assess which of 24 provisions tracked by the Investor Responsibility Research Center (IRRC) had the greatest impact on shareholder value. The index includes staggered boards, limits to shareholder bylaw amendments, supermajority requirements for mergers, supermajority requirements for charter amendments, poison pills, and golden parachutes.

115 Cain et al. (2017), Cohen and Wang (2013).

116 Bebchuk et al. (2010).

117 Masulis et al. (2007).

118 Atanassov (2013).

119 Souther (2016).

120 Cremers and Ferrell (2014).

121 Randolph et al. (2018).

122 Heron and Lie (2015).

123 Goktan and Kieschnick (2012).

124 Dimopoulos and Sacchetto (2014) estimate that in about three-fourths of deals involving only one bidder, the acquisition price paid is determined largely by the degree of target resistance.

125 Ertugrul (2015).

126 Cremers et al. (2017), Amihud and Stoyanov (2017).

127 Bebchuk and Cohen (2017) dispute Cremers et al. (2017) findings.

128 Chen (2012) argues that by reducing concern over takeovers, managers are less inclined to engage in high-risk strategies and more willing to provide detailed financial disclosure. Both activities aid bondholders.

129 Duru et al. (2013).

130 Ahn and Shrestha (2013).

131 Di Meo et al. (2017).

132 Bhojraj et al. (2017).

133 Liu and Mulherin (2018).

134 Bates and Becher (2017).

135 Jandik and Lallemand (2015).

136 Examples of investor protections include laws requiring firms to give investors easy access to financial statements and providing shareholders’ with the ability to vote out directors by proxy.

137 Jandik et al. (2017).

138 Stout (2002).

139 Johnson et al. (2015).

140 “Ring fencing” means in this context that Nextra Energy would not have been able to transfer Oncor assets and income for other purposes. For example, Oncor assets could not be used as collateral for loans whose proceeds were to be reinvested outside of Oncor operations. How Oncor’s income would be used would be determined by a board of directors consisting mostly of independent directors who were more likely to use the income for reinvestment in Oncor and not for payment of dividends to the parent.

"To view the full reference list for the book, click here"

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset