Chapter 11
Markowitz Portfolios

Portfolio choice with mean–variance preferences was proposed by Markowitz (1952 1959). The approach introduced the idea of balancing risk and return to find an optimal portfolio.

Markowitz approach can be used in the single period portfolio selection. Let c011-math-001 be the portfolio return. In the Markowitz approach there exists three ways to choose the portfolio:

  1. 1. Maximize the variance penalized expected return
    equation
  2. where c011-math-002 is the risk aversion coefficient. Parameter c011-math-003 measures the investor's relative risk aversion, as defined in (9.31).
  3. 2. Minimize the variance c011-math-004 under a minimal requirement for the expected return: c011-math-005, where c011-math-006 is the minimal requirement for the expected return.
  4. 3. Maximize the expected return c011-math-007 under a condition that the variance is not too large: c011-math-008 where c011-math-009 is the largest allowed standard deviation for the return.

Here c011-math-010 and c011-math-011 mean the conditional expectation and the conditional variance, conditional on the information available at time c011-math-012.

The variance penalized expected return was already discussed in Section 9.2.1. The variance penalized expected return is convenient because it involves explicitly the risk aversion parameter c011-math-013, which makes it possible to find a connection to the maximization of an expected utility. The other two approaches involve risk aversion more implicitly. When variance is minimized under a minimal requirement c011-math-014 for the expected return, then the minimal requirement c011-math-015 is a risk aversion parameter, because smaller values of c011-math-016 are associated with more risk aversion. When the expected return is maximized under a condition that the variance is less than or equal to c011-math-017, then c011-math-018 is a risk aversion parameter, because smaller values of c011-math-019 indicate more risk aversion.

We explain with the help of Markowitz bullets the concepts of the minimum variance portfolio, the tangency portfolio, and the efficient frontier. This is done in Section 11.3.

The method of Lagrange multipliers appears in Section 11.1.2 and in Section 11.2. The method of Lagrange multipliers is a useful general method of optimization. The method of Lagrange multipliers helps to cope with the restriction that the sum of portfolio weights have to be equal to one. Further complications appear when we want to restrict ourselves to long-only portfolios, or to make some other additional restrictions on the portfolio weights. We do not consider these additional complications.

We use the notations of Section 9.1. The portfolio return was defined in (9.3) as

equation

where

equation

is the vector of the portfolio weights, c011-math-020 is the transpose of the column vector c011-math-021, and

equation

is the vector of the gross returns of the portfolio components. The portfolio weights satisfy the constraint

equation

Thus, c011-math-022 and

equation

where c011-math-023 is called the excess return. Since we consider only single period portfolio selection, we do not need the time subscript in the notation. Thus, we denote the portfolio vector of risky assets by

equation

Also, since the expectations and variances are conditional on c011-math-024, the risk-free rate is a constant (known at time c011-math-025). We will denote the risk-free rate by

equation

The vector of means and the covariance matrix of the risky assets is denoted by

equation

where c011-math-026 and c011-math-027 is the c011-math-028 matrix with elements c011-math-029. Now,

equation

Section 11.1 considers the maximization of the variance penalized expected return. Section 11.2 considers minimization of the variance under a minimal requirement for the expected return. Section 11.3 considers concepts related to the Markowitz portfolio theory, such as the minimum variance portfolio and the tangency portfolio. Section 11.4 considers further topics related to Markowitz portfolio theory. Section 11.5 applies Markowitz formulas to portfolio selection.

11.1 Variance Penalized Expected Return

We consider the maximization of the variance penalized expected return. Section 11.1.1 considers portfolios where the risk-free rate is included. Section 11.1.2 considers portfolios without the risk-free rate.

11.1.1 Variance Penalization with the Risk-Free Rate

Let us consider the maximization of the variance penalized expected return when the risk-free rate is included. We consider first the general case of c011-math-030 risky asset and then the special cases of one risky asset and two risky assets.

11.1.1.1 Several Risky Assets and the Risk-Free Rate

The portfolio components are c011-math-031 risky assets and the risk-free rate. Let the return of the risk-free investment be c011-math-032. We allocate the proportion c011-math-033 into the risk-free investment. Then the portfolio return is

equation

We choose the weight vector c011-math-034 as maximizing

11.1 equation

Derivating with respect to c011-math-036 and setting the partial derivatives to zero gives

equation

Thus,

equation

11.1.1.2 One Risky Asset and the Risk-Free Rate

Let us invest the proportion c011-math-037 to a stock and c011-math-038 to the risk-free rate whose gross return is c011-math-039. Now the gross return of the portfolio is

equation

where c011-math-040 is the return of the stock. Let the expected return of the stock be c011-math-041 and the variance c011-math-042. Then,

Setting the derivative with respect to c011-math-044 to zero and solving for c011-math-045 gives the maximizer of (11.2) as

Let c011-math-047 be the optimal weight of the long-only portfolio. The maximizer c011-math-048 of (11.2) under the restriction that c011-math-049 is obtained by projecting the unrestricted solution on c011-math-050. Thus,

11.4 equation

where c011-math-052 is given in (11.3).

11.1.1.3 Two Risky Assets and the Risk-Free Rate

Let us have two stocks and the risk-free rate and let us invest the proportion c011-math-053 in the first stock, proportion c011-math-054 in the second stock, and proportion c011-math-055 in the risk-free rate. Now the portfolio return is

equation

where c011-math-056 is the return of the first stock and c011-math-057 is the return of the second stock. Let the expected returns of the stocks be c011-math-058, c011-math-059 and let the variances of the returns be c011-math-060, c011-math-061. Denote the covariance of the returns by c011-math-062. We have

equation

Setting derivatives with respect to c011-math-063 and c011-math-064 to zero gives

equation

Thus,1

equation

and

equation

11.1.2 Variance Penalization without the Risk-Free Rate

Let us consider the maximization of the variance penalized expected return when the risk-free rate is excluded. We solve first the case of c011-math-066 risky assets and then the case of two risky assets.

11.1.2.1 Several Risky Assets

The maximization of the variance penalized expected return chooses the weight vector c011-math-067 as maximizing

where c011-math-069 is the vector of length c011-math-070 whose all elements are equal to one, so that the constraint is

equation

Let us maximize

equation

under the constraint c011-math-071. We use the method of Lagrange multipliers and maximize the Lagrange function

equation

where c011-math-072 is the Lagrange multiplier. Derivating with respect to c011-math-073 and c011-math-074 and setting the partial derivatives to zero we get

equation

Thus,

equation

Let us solve c011-math-075 from c011-math-076, which leads to

equation

and finally

equation

11.1.2.2 Two Risky Assets

Let us have two stocks and put the proportion c011-math-077 to the first stock and proportion c011-math-078 to the second stock. Now,

equation

Let the expected returns of the stocks be c011-math-079, c011-math-080 and let the variances of the returns be c011-math-081, c011-math-082. Denote the covariance of the returns by c011-math-083. We have

equation

Setting the derivative with respect to c011-math-084 to zero and solving for c011-math-085 gives

Note that the maximizer c011-math-087 under the restriction that c011-math-088 is obtained by projecting the unrestricted solution:

11.7 equation

where c011-math-090 is given in (11.6).

11.2 Minimizing Variance under a Sufficient Expected Return

We consider the minimization of the variance under a condition that the expected return should be sufficiently large. Section 11.2.1 considers portfolios where the risk-free rate is included. Section 11.2.2 considers portfolios without the risk-free rate.

11.2.1 Minimizing Variance with the Risk-Free Rate

We consider first the case of c011-math-091 risky assets and the risk-free investment, and then the case of one risky assets and the risk-free investment.

11.2.1.1 Several Risky Assets and the Risk-Free Rate

Let us consider the case of c011-math-092 risky assets and a risk-free investment. We want to find the weight vector minimizing

11.8 equation

where c011-math-094. We should choose c011-math-095, so that the required expected return is not smaller than the risk-free return.

The return vector of the risky investments is denoted by c011-math-096, the expectation vector is c011-math-097, the covariance matrix is c011-math-098, and the risk-free return is c011-math-099. The proportion c011-math-100 is invested in the risk-free asset. The return of the portfolio is

equation

The expected return of the portfolio is

equation

Let us find c011-math-101 minimizing

equation

under the constraint

equation

where c011-math-102 is a constant. Define the Lagrange function

equation

where c011-math-103 is the Lagrange multiplier. We solve the equation

equation

to get

equation

The constraint can be written as

equation

which implies

equation

and

equation

Thus, the vector of the weights of the risky investments is

equation

11.2.1.2 One Risky Asset and the Risk-Free Rate

Let us consider the case where we have one risky asset with return c011-math-104 and a risk-free investment with return c011-math-105. Let the expected return of the risky asset be c011-math-106 and the variance c011-math-107. Let us invest the proportion c011-math-108 to the risky asset and the proportion c011-math-109 to the risk-free asset. The return of the portfolio is

equation

The expected return of the portfolio is

equation

and the variance of the portfolio is

equation

We want that the expected return should be at least c011-math-110 and we minimize the variance under this condition. Thus, we want to find c011-math-111 minimizing

equation

under the constraint

equation

Define the Lagrange function

equation

where c011-math-112 is the Lagrange multiplier. The solution of the equation

equation

is

equation

The constraint c011-math-113 implies c011-math-114 Thus, the weight of the risky investment is

equation

When c011-math-115, then c011-math-116.

11.2.2 Minimizing Variance without the Risk-Free Rate

We want to choose the weight vector c011-math-117 minimizing

11.9 equation

where c011-math-119, and we should choose c011-math-120, so that the required expected return is not smaller than the risk-free return.

Let us consider portfolios of c011-math-121 risky assets and exclude the risk-free investment. The return vector of the risky investments is denoted by c011-math-122. Let us denote c011-math-123 and c011-math-124. Then,

equation

We minimize

equation

under the constraints

equation

where c011-math-125 is the column vector of length c011-math-126 whose elements are equal to 1, and c011-math-127 is a constant. The Lagrange function is

equation

where c011-math-128 are the Lagrange multipliers. The solution of the equation2

equation

is

equation

To get c011-math-131 and c011-math-132 we need to solve the equations

equation

Denoting c011-math-133, c011-math-134, and c011-math-135, we get

equation

Then, the vector of the portfolio weights is

equation

where c011-math-136.

11.3 Markowitz Bullets

A Markowitz bullet is a scatter plot of points, where each point corresponds to a portfolio, the c011-math-137-coordinate of a point is the standard deviation of the return of the portfolio, and the c011-math-138-coordinate of a point is the expected return of the portfolio. The scatter plot is called a bullet because the boundary of the scatter plot is a part of a hyperbola, and thus its shape resembles the shape of a bullet.3

Figure 11.1 plots a collection of portfolios which are obtained from two risky assets. The expected net returns of the assets are 1 and 0.5. The standard deviations are 2 and 1. The correlation between the returns of the risky assets varies from c011-math-143 to 1. Panel (a) shows long-only portfolios. The blue wedge on the left shows all portfolios that can be obtained when correlation is c011-math-144. The orange vector on the right shows all portfolios that can be obtained when correlation is 1. When correlation is c011-math-145, then there exists a portfolio with zero variance. The portfolio with zero variance should have the same return as the risk-free rate, to exclude arbitrage. Panel (b) shows portfolios that can be obtained from the two risky assets when shorting is allowed. The weight of an asset varies between c011-math-146 and 1.5.

Illustration of Markowitz bullets: Portfolios of two risky assets when correlation varies.

Figure 11.1 Markowitz bullets: Portfolios of two risky assets when correlation varies. (a) Shown are long-only portfolios that can be obtained from two risky assets when correlation between the risky assets varies between c011-math-147 and c011-math-148. (b) Shorting is allowed.

Figure 11.2 shows portfolios obtained from three risky assets as a blue area. The three risky assets are shown as orange points. The correlations between the risky assets are 0.2, 0.5, and 0.6. Panel (a) shows all long-only portfolios and panel (b) shows portfolios when shorting is allowed with restrictions. The shapes of the blue areas are irregular but the left boundaries are parts of hyperbolas.

Illustration of Markowitz bullets: Portfolios of three risky assets.

Figure 11.2 Markowitz bullets: Portfolios of three risky assets. (a) Long-only portfolios that can be obtained from three risky assets. (b) Portfolios when shorting is allowed.

Figure 11.3 shows a Markowitz bullet of long-only portfolios, when the risk-free rate is included and the borrowing is allowed. Panel (a) shows as a blue curve long-only portfolios whose components are two risky assets with correlation c011-math-149. The green point shows the minimum variance portfolio. The black point shows the risk-free investment whose net return is 0.1 and the variance is zero. The red point shows the tangency portfolio. The red line joining the risk-free investment and the tangency portfolio corresponds to the long-only portfolios whose components are the risk-free investment and the tangency portfolio. The yellow area corresponds to the long-only portfolios whose components are the risk-free investment and one of the portfolios on the blue curve; these are all possible long-only portfolios. Panel (b) shows portfolios from two risky assets and the risk-free investment when the weight of the risk-free investment is allowed to be negative, which amounts to allowing leveraging by borrowing.

Illustration of Markowitz bullet: Long-only portfolios and leveraging.

Figure 11.3 Markowitz bullet: Long-only portfolios and leveraging. Panel (a) shows long-only portfolios for two risky assets and the risk-free investment. Panel (b) shows portfolios for two risky assets and the risk-free investment when the weight of the risk-free investment is allowed to be negative, which means the borrowing is allowed.

We can use Figure 11.3 to define the concepts of the minimum variance portfolio, the tangency portfolio, and the efficient frontier.

  1. 1. The minimum variance portfolio is the portfolio of risky assets whose variance is the smallest among all portfolios of risky assets. When the risk-free rate is included, then the risk-free investment has the minimum variance zero.
  2. 2. Efficient frontier is the collection of those portfolio vectors that have the expected return greater than or equal to the expected return of the minimum variance portfolio:

    In Figure 11.3(a) the efficient frontier without the risk-free rate is the part of the blue curve going upward from the red point, but when the risk-free rate is included, then the red vector from the risk-free asset to the tangency portfolio, followed by the blue curve shows the efficient frontier. The efficient frontier consists of possible portfolios a rational investor should consider, because these portfolios have a higher expected return with the same variance than other portfolios. Adding the risk-free rate gives the possibility to get portfolios with a smaller standard deviation than any of the pure stock portfolios: some of the portfolios on the red vector are such that the standard error is smaller than the standard deviation of any of the pure stock portfolios.

    In Figure 11.3(b) borrowing is allowed. The borrowed money is invested in the stocks. Now the efficient frontier is the red half line starting from the risk-free investment and passing the tangency portfolio. We see that a rational investor chooses only portfolios that are a combination of the risk-free investment and the tangency portfolio. The other portfolios have a smaller expected return for the same variance.

  3. 3. The tangency portfolio is a portfolio which has the largest Sharpe ratio. Indeed, the tangency portfolio maximizes the slope of the vector drawn from the risk-free asset to a pure stock portfolio. The slope of the vector from the point c011-math-150 to the point c011-math-151 is equal to the Sharpe ratio c011-math-152, where c011-math-153 is the return of the risk-free asset and c011-math-154 is the return of a portfolio.
  4. 4. It can be argued that the tangency portfolio, shown as the red point in the blue curve, is in fact the market portfolio, because the rational investor buys only a combination of the tangency portfolio and the risk-free asset, and thus the price of the tangency portfolio is in the equilibrium equal to the price of the market portfolio.

Figure 11.4 plots standard deviations and means for a collection of portfolios when shorting of a stock is allowed. Panel (a) shows portfolios from two risky assets. The blue part shows the long-only portfolios, the orange part shows the portfolios where the less risky stock is shorted, and the purple part shows the portfolios where the more risky stock is shorted. The green bullet shows the minimum variance portfolio, the black bullet shows the risk-free investment, and the red bullet shows the tangency portfolio. Panel (b) shows portfolios of two risky assets and a risk-free investment when the weight of the risk-free investment is allowed to be negative, which amounts to allowing leveraging by borrowing.

Illustration of Markowitz bullet: Shorting and leveraging.

Figure 11.4 Markowitz bullet: Shorting and leveraging. Panel (a) shows portfolios from two risky assets, and from two risky assets and the risk-free investment. Panel (b) shows portfolios from two risky assets and a risk-free investment when the weight of the risk-free investment is allowed to be negative, so that borrowing is possible.

Figure 11.5 shows how increasing the number of basis assets makes the Markowitz bullet larger. The blue hyperbola shows portfolios that can be obtained from two risky assets, the green area shows portfolios that can be obtained from three risky assets, and the yellow area shows portfolios that can be obtained from four risky assets. The orange points show the risky assets. The covariances between the returns of the risky assets are zero.

Illustration of Markowitz bullet: Uncorrelated assets.

Figure 11.5 Markowitz bullet: Uncorrelated assets. Markowitz bullets are shown for an increasing number of assets: blue curve shows portfolios from two risky assets, the green area portfolios from three risky assets, and the yellow area portfolios from four risky assets, when the risky assets are uncorrelated.

Figure 11.6 studies a Markowitz bullet of the daily returns of S&P 500 components. The data is described in Section 2.4.5. Panel (a) shows a scatter plot of the annualized sample standard deviations and annualized sample means of the excess returns of the stocks included in the S&P 500 components data. The red bullet shows the location of the S&P 500 index. The blue bullet is at the origin: we take the risk-free rate equal to zero because the Markowitz bullet is computed from the excess returns.4 Panel (b) shows a kernel density estimate of the distribution of the Sharpe ratios of the stocks included in S&P 500 components data. The red vertical line indicates the Sharpe ratio of the S&P 500 index. We see that the S&P 500 is not a tangent portfolio, since its Sharpe ratio is smaller than the most Sharpe ratios of the individual stocks.

Illustration of Markowitz bullet: S&P 500 components.

Figure 11.6 Markowitz bullet: S&P 500 components. (a) A scatter plot of annualized sample standard deviations and means of excess returns of a collection of stocks in the S&P 500 index. (b) A kernel density estimate of the distribution of the Sharpe ratios.

11.4 Further Topics in Markowitz Portfolio Selection

11.4.1 Estimation

In order to apply Markowitz formulas, we have to estimate the vector c011-math-155 of expected returns and the covariance matrix c011-math-156 of the returns of the risky assets.

The sample means, sample variances, and sample covariances could be applied. However, we have discussed many other methods. Chapter 6 discusses various prediction methods that could be applied to estimate (predict) c011-math-157. Chapter 7 discusses various methods for volatility prediction that could be used to estimate c011-math-158, c011-math-159. Analogous methods can be used to estimate the covariances c011-math-160, c011-math-161, c011-math-162. For example, Section 5.4 considers multivariate time series models which are relevant for covariance prediction.

In the estimation of the covariance matrix c011-math-163 we have to take the curse of dimensionality into account, since the number c011-math-164 of risky assets can be high relative to the sample size. Note that the covariance matrix involves only the pairwise covariances, so that high dimensionality does not make it difficult to estimate any single component of the matrix c011-math-165. However, there are c011-math-166 covariances, and a simultaneous estimation of such a large number of parameters is difficult.

11.4.2 Penalizing Techniques

Let us consider minimization of the variance of the portfolio return under a minimal requirement for the expected return. Let c011-math-167 be the return vector of risky assets with c011-math-168 and c011-math-169. Then the expected return of the portfolio is c011-math-170 and the variance is c011-math-171, where c011-math-172 is the vector of portfolio weights. We want to find weights c011-math-173 such that

equation

is minimized under the constraints

equation

where c011-math-174 is the requirement for the expected return of the portfolio. The minimization problem is equivalent to finding c011-math-175 such that

equation

is minimized under the same constraints. Let us assume to have observed historical returns c011-math-176 of the basis assets. The empirical version of the minimization problem is to find c011-math-177 such that

equation

is minimized under the constraints

equation

where c011-math-178. Brodie et al. (2009) proposed to add a penalization term and find c011-math-179 minimizing

equation

under the same constraints, where c011-math-180 is the regularizing parameter. The approach is similar to the approach in Lasso regression of Tibshirani (1996).

DeMiguel et al. (2009) showed that it is difficult to significantly or consistently outperform the naive strategy in which each available asset is given an equal weight in the portfolio.

11.4.3 Principal Components Analysis

Let c011-math-181 be the c011-math-182 vector of the expected returns of the c011-math-183 risky assets. Given the c011-math-184 vector of portfolio weights c011-math-185, the return of the portfolio is c011-math-186. Let c011-math-187 be the c011-math-188 covariance matrix of the returns of the risky assets. We can make the principal component analysis of the covariance matrix and write

equation

where c011-math-189 is the c011-math-190 matrix whose columns are the eigenvectors of c011-math-191 and c011-math-192 is the c011-math-193 diagonal matrix, whose diagonal elements are the eigenvalues of c011-math-194. We get c011-math-195 uncorrelated principal portfolios whose return vector is c011-math-196. We can think of these principal portfolios as new basic assets and write any portfolio in terms of the principal components. If the original weights are c011-math-197, then the new weights are c011-math-198. Now we can calculate the variance of the portfolio as

equation

where c011-math-199 are the eigenvalues of c011-math-200. We can define the diversification distribution

equation

where c011-math-201. We can say that a portfolio is better diversified, if the diversification distribution is closer to the uniform distribution. This can be measured by

equation

Partovi and Caputo (2004) used principal portfolios in their discussion of efficient frontier, and Meucci (2009) presented the idea of the diversification distribution.

11.5 Examples of Markowitz Portfolio Selection

We illustrate Markowitz portfolio selection using as the basic assets the S&P 500 and Nasdaq-100 indexes. The daily data set of S&P 500 and Nasdaq-100 is described in Section 2.4.2.

We consider portfolio selection without the risk-free rate. We maximize the variance penalized expected return (11.5) both without restrictions and with the restriction to the long-only weights.

Figure 11.7 shows the time series of the Markowitz weights of S&P 500. Panel (a) shows the unrestricted Markowitz weights and panel (b) shows the long-only Markowitz weights. The risk aversion parameter takes values c011-math-202 (black, red, blue, green, and orange). When the weight of S&P 500 is denoted by c011-math-203, then the weight of Nasdaq-100 is c011-math-204. We have estimated the mean vector and the covariance matrix sequentially, using the sample means and the sample covariance matrices. We start when there are 1000 observations (4 years of data). The weight of S&P 500 increases when the risk aversion parameter c011-math-205 increases. After year 2000, the weight of S&P 500 jumps higher.

Graphical illustration of S&P 500 and Nasdaq-100: Markowitz weights.

Figure 11.7 S&P 500 and Nasdaq-100: Markowitz weights. The time series of the weights for the S&P 500. (a) The unrestricted weights and (b) the long-only weights. The risk aversion parameter takes values c011-math-206 (black, red, blue, green, and orange).

Figure 11.8 shows the Sharpe ratios, annualized means and annualized standard deviations, as a function of risk aversion parameter c011-math-207. Panel (a) shows the Sharpe ratios. The black line with labels “1” is obtained when the unrestricted weights are used and the green line with labels “2” is obtained when the long-only weights are used. The horizontal lines show the Sharpe ratios for S&P 500 (blue) and Nasdaq-100 (red). The risk-free rate is deduced from the 1-month US bill rates, described in Section 2.4.3. The highest value of the Sharpe ratio is obtained for small risk aversion. When the risk aversion increases, the Sharpe ratios of the Markowitz portfolio approach the Sharpe ratio of S&P 500. Panel (b) shows the annualized means as a function of the risk aversion and panel (c) shows the annualized standard deviations. Both means and standard deviations increase sharply when the risk aversion parameter decreases.

Graphical illustration of S&P 500 and Nasdaq-100: Sharpe ratios, means, and standard deviations.

Figure 11.8 S&P 500 and Nasdaq-100: Sharpe ratios, means, and standard deviations. (a) The Sharpe ratios as a function of c011-math-208; (b) the annualized means; (c) the annualized standard deviations. The black line with labels “1” is obtained when the unrestricted weights are used and the green line with labels “2” is obtained when the long-only weights are used.

equation

This leads to

equation
..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset